Abstract
Researchers often identify degree effects by including degree attainment (D) and years of schooling (S) in a wage model, yet the source of independent variation in these measures is not well understood. We argue that S is negatively correlated with ability among degree-holders because the most able graduate the fastest, but positively correlated among dropouts because the most able benefit from increased schooling. Using NLSY79 data, we find support for this argument; our findings also suggest that highest grade completed is the preferred measure of S for dropouts, while age at school exit is a more informative measure for degree-holders.
I. Introduction
A central issue in labor economics is why credentialed workers (those with high school diplomas or college degrees) earn more than their non credentialed counterparts. Such degree effects are consistent with sorting models of education (Arrow 1973; Spence 1973; Stiglitz 1975; Weiss 1983) in which employers use credentials to identify workers with desirable traits that cannot be directly observed.1 Degree effects also are generated by human capital models (Becker 1964; Card 1995; Card 1999) if good learners are the ones who stay in school long enough to earn credentials, or if lumpiness in the learning process leads to more skill acquisition in degree years than in preceding years (Chiswick 1973; Lange and Topel 2006). Despite difficulties in distinguishing between these two competing models, the sorting versus human capital debate has dominated the degree effects literature for over 30 years.
Largely overlooked in this debate is the role of functional form in the interpretation of degree effects. In the earliest empirical studies (Taubman and Wales 1973; Hungerford and Solon 1987), degree effects were identified by including a nonlinear function of years of school (S) or categorical measures of degree attainment (D) in a log-wage model. More recently, analysts have taken advantage of richer survey data to implement a different identification strategy: Rather than include S or D in their wage models, they control for both S and D (Frazis 1993; Jaeger and Page 1996; Arkes 1999; Park 1999; Ferrer and Riddell 2002). The interpretation of the resulting degree effects—defined as the wage gap between credentialed and noncredentialed workers conditional on years of schooling—is the focus of our analysis.
When both S and D are included in a wage model, degree effects are identified because individuals with a given amount of schooling differ in their degree status or, stated differently, because years of schooling vary among individuals within a given degree category. We begin by considering how individuals’ schooling decisions could generate this variation in S and D. Among orthodox human capital and sorting models, only the sorting-cum-learning model of Weiss (1983) explains why S and D might vary independently.2 In Weiss’s model, individuals attend school for S years and then take a test. High-ability individuals pass the test and earn a degree, while low-ability individuals terminate their schooling without a degree. While this behavioral framework justifies the inclusion of S and D in a wage model, it is inconsistent with the fact that individuals take varying amounts of time to earn identical degrees.
The empirical literature provides a number of explanations for why time to degree might vary across individuals. After documenting that the time typically needed to earn a college degree increased significantly between the 1970s and 1990s, Bound, Lovenheim, and Turner (2007); Bound and Turner (2007); and Turner (2004) consider such explanatory factors as declines in student preparedness as more high school graduates were drawn into college; corresponding declines in course availability and other college resources that delay degree completion; and credit constraints that led to increased in-school employment and enrollment interruptions among college students. Analyses of employment among high school and college students (Ruhm 1997; Light 1999; Oettinger 1999; Light 2001; Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner 2003; Parent 2006) and college transfer patterns (Hilmer 1997; McCormick and Carroll 1997; Hilmer 2000; Light and Strayer 2004) provide additional insights into why students vary in their time to degree completion.
To our knowledge, neither the theoretical nor empirical literature has considered a particular pattern that we find in the data: Wages increase with years of school (S) among both high school and college dropouts, but decrease in S among both high school and college graduates. Given the lack of compelling explanations for the type of variation in S and D that would generate this particular pattern, we present a simple human capital model in which (i) individuals differ in ability; (ii) high-ability individuals acquire more skill than low-ability individuals during each year of school; (iii) degrees are awarded once a given skill threshold is reached; and (iv) lumpiness in learning causes individuals with varying ability levels to terminate their schooling upon crossing an identical degree threshold. In addition to predicting that high-ability individuals earn degrees and low-ability individuals do not, this model demonstrates how ability might be negatively correlated with time spent in school among degree holders: Everyone in this population reaches the same level of achievement, but the most able reach the threshold in the shortest time. Among individuals who do not earn a degree, however, those with the most ability stay in school the longest because they benefit from additional skill investments.
Our schooling model provides a rationale for including both S and D in the log-wage function. Moreover, it leads us to specify a wage function in which the S slope varies across degree categories, and it predicts that the S slope is negative for degree holders and positive for nondegree holders. In contrast, earlier studies include independent dummy variables for each degree category (D) and for schooling (S) (Frazis 1993; Jaeger and Page 1996; Arkes 1999; Park 1999; Ferrer and Riddell 2002), or they specify a fully interacted model with a dummy variable for every S–D cell (Jaeger and Page 1996; Park 1999). In the absence of an explicit theoretical justification for these functional forms, it is difficult to interpret the estimates.3
In estimating our log-wage model with data from the 1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, we consider two additional issues. First, we acknowledge that the independent variation in S and D used for identification can arise from reporting errors as well as from the optimizing behavior described by our model. Because models that control for both S and D rely on variation in S within each degree category, the estimates are more vulnerable to noise than are estimates that rely on the total variation in the data. To contend with measurement error, we reestimate our wage equations with S and D data that are judged to be “clean” to determine whether seemingly error-ridden observations are driving our results. While misreporting of both S and D has been widely explored (Ashenfelter and Krueger 1994; Kane, Rouse, and Staiger 1999; Black, Berger, and Scott 2000; Bound, Brown, and Mathiowetz 2001; Flores-Lagunes and Light 2006), estimates from the “clean” sample suggest that measurement error is not an important source of the independent variation in S and D used to identify degree effects.
Second, we argue that the most common measure of years of school—namely, highest grade completed—is not always the preferred measure. For degree holders, we wish to know how long it takes to earn the credential. However, time to completion is not fully captured by highest grade completed if the latter measures credits earned toward a degree—for example, high school graduates may report having completed Grade 12 regardless of whether they earned their diploma in three, four, or five years. For this reason, age at school exit is our preferred measure of time spent in school for degree holders. Among dropouts, where our goal is to measure the skill acquisition that takes place prior to school exit, the opposite is true: Highest grade completed (that is, progress made toward a degree) is likely to be a better measure than age at school exit. In light of these concerns, we use both highest grade completed and age at school exit (conditional on work experience gained while in school) as alternative measures of S in our wage models.
Our estimates reveal that the marginal effect of S varies across degree categories in the systematic manner predicted by our model: Each year of S is associated with higher wages among high school and college dropouts, and with lower wages among high school and college graduates. For the two dropout categories, the positive slope is larger in magnitude (ranging from 0.02 to 0.05) and more precisely estimated when S is measured as highest grade completed than when S is measured as age at school exit. For the two degree categories, the negative estimates (ranging from −0.002 to −0.03) become much more precise when we measure S as age at school exit rather than as highest grade completed. The independent variation in S and D observed in the data appears to reflect important skill differences among individuals with a common degree status. By recasting degree effects as time in school effects conditional on D, we learn that dropouts who stay in school the longest are the most highly skilled of their type, as are graduates who complete their degrees in the shortest time.
II. Schooling Model
Our objective is to show why time spent in school (S) varies among individuals with a given degree status (D) and, in particular, why S is positively (negatively) correlated with ability among dropouts (graduates). We begin with a straightforward extension of Card’s (1995, 1999) formalization of Becker’s (1964) seminal model, in which individuals terminate their schooling when the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost. Becker (1964) and Card (1995, 1999) consider a single observed dimension—years of schooling (S)—in which to assess individuals: The more S a worker has, the more skill and ability he is expected to embody. We augment this framework by assuming a degree is awarded to any individual who crosses a given skill threshold. We also assume that lumpiness in learning leads to a discontinuity in the human capital production function at the degree threshold. The discontinuity induces individuals with a range of abilities to terminate their schooling upon earning the degree—however, the more able among this group reach the threshold sooner than their less able counterparts because they acquire skill at a faster rate. Individuals who lack the ability to earn a degree never face the discontinuity, and instead make their schooling decision precisely as described in the Becker and Card models. Thus, dropouts exhibit the familiar pattern in which more able individuals stay in school longer than less able individuals.
To formalize these arguments, we consider a group of individuals who are heterogeneous with respect to their innate ability, face no ex ante uncertainty about their ability, and are identical with respect to all cost-related factors such as discount rates and tastes. In addition, we assume that schools offer a single, identical degree and are essentially indistinguishable from one another—that is, we abstract from the role of school characteristics and programs of study in affecting how much a given individual will learn in a given amount of time. We make these simplifying assumptions in order to highlight the key features of our model. After presenting the model in Section IIA, we discuss in Section IIB the extent to which additional real world complexities might influence students’ schooling decisions.
A. Effects of Lumpiness in Learning on Schooling Decisions
We assume individual i chooses years of schooling (Si) to maximize the utility function
(1)
where Ki and Ai represent individual-specific acquired skill and innate ability, respectively, and r is the discount rate. The function K(Si)=g(Si|Ai) is the human capital production function that describes how each additional year of school translates into additional skill, and C(Si)=rSi is the associated cost function. In contrast to Card’s (1995, 1999) formulation we include skill, rather than earnings, as an argument in the utility function; the individual seeks to maximize the discounted, present value of skill which, along with ability, determines his postschool earnings.4 The substitution of Ki for earnings allows us to highlight the relationship between years of school and degree attainment, which we assume occurs whenever skill reaches the threshold KD. Following Card (1995, 1999), we assume skill increases with S at a decreasing rate, and that the marginal benefit of S increases in A. However, we also assume that a discontinuity arises in g(Si|Ai) as the threshold KD is approached. This discontinuity only affects individuals whose ability is high enough to enable them to attain a degree, so we defer further discussion of this feature until we consider these individuals’ schooling decisions.
In Figure 1, we illustrate the schooling decisions of two individuals with relatively low levels of ability. Regardless of how long these individuals stay in school, their skill level does not get close enough to the threshold KD for lumpiness in learning to come into play. As a result, both individuals simply choose the schooling level at which the slope of their (continuous) production path equals the constant marginal cost r. For the individual with ability level A1, this schooling level is S1; for his counterpart with the higher ability level A2, the optimal schooling level is S2. In short, individuals in this range of the ability distribution—all of whom leave school without degrees—exhibit the familiar pattern (Becker 1964; Card 1995; Card 1999) of positive correlation between ability, years of school, and skill.
Time in school for low ability (A1) and high ability (A2) dropouts
Next, we consider the schooling decisions of two individuals whose ability levels are sufficiently high to make degree attainment a possibility. Figure 2 shows that in the absence of any discontinuity, the individual with ability A3 finds his optimum at point b′, while the individual with higher ability A4 chooses a′. As each individual approaches skill threshold KD, however, his path shifts upward by a fixed amount. The upward shift in the production function (shown by the solid lines) is caused by lumpiness in learning—that is, individuals experience a contemporaneous increment in their skill level once they complete a program of study. This feature of the learning process was first suggested by Chiswick (1973) to explain how degree attainment could be associated with a larger wage increment than nondegree years in the absence of job market signaling.
Time in school for low ability (A3) and high ability (A4) graduates
For the type A4 individual, the discontinuity shown in Figure 2 happens to occur at the skill level associated with S4 years of school, which is the point at which he would terminate his schooling in the absence of a discontinuity. The individual reaches an optimum (point a) on the higher path, and leaves school with a degree after S4 years. The discontinuity induces the lower ability individual to move from point b′ to point b (that is, to leave school with a degree after S3 years). More generally, individuals in this ability range can choose to stay in school longer in order to exploit the benefits of lumpiness in learning, but the most able among them earn their degrees the fastest.
Thus far, we have assumed that lumpiness in learning produces a contemporaneous skill boost but does not affect the marginal cost or marginal benefit of S. If the cost of continued schooling increases or tastes change once a degree is earned, then the discontinuity in the production function could be accompanied by an increase in r. If the productivity burst associated with degree completion is followed by a productivity slowdown, then the production function could not only shift upward but also flatten. Under either scenario (or a combination of the two), high-ability individuals might opt to leave school sooner in response to the discontinuity. In Figure 3, we compare the type A3 individual from Figure 2 to an individual with ability A5 (which exceeds A4) under a scenario where marginal cost (r) increases once KD is reached. In the absence of a discontinuity or cost change, the individual with ability A5 would proceed beyond skill level KD to point c′.5 If the upward shift in his production path is accompanied by an increase in r, as shown in Figure 3, he chooses point c. In other words, he opts not to proceed beyond the degree. More generally, any increase in marginal cost or decrease in marginal benefit that accompanies lumpiness in learning can cause type A5 individuals to join the type A3 and type A4 individuals in leaving school upon crossing the degree threshold. This leads to even more variation in S among individuals with identical degrees, while maintaining a negative relationship between S and A.
Time in school for “higher” ability (A5) graduate who leaves school sooner in response to discontinuity
B. Additional Considerations
Our simple extension of Card’s (1995, 1999) schooling model demonstrates how particular patterns in the data might arise. While the pattern for dropouts (a positive relationship between S and A) emerges directly from the Card model, the reverse pattern for graduates is generated because we assume lumpiness in learning in conjunction with the notion that degrees are awarded when a given skill level is reached. The notion that S might represent something different for graduates than for dropouts—and, as we demonstrate in Section V, the fact that the dropout-graduate contrast holds at both the high school and college level—appears not to have been analyzed elsewhere in the literature.
The literature has extensively explored the broader issue of why time in school and time to degree (especially college degree) vary across individuals. Becker (1964) and Card (1995, 1999) describe precisely how factors affecting both marginal benefit and marginal cost affect a given individual’s schooling attainment. Bound, Lovenheim, and Turner (2007); Bound and Turner (2007); and Turner (2004) consider a range of factors to explain why the timing of college degree attainment slowed during the 1970s and 1980s. Research on the employment of high school and college students (Ruhm 1997; Light 1999; Oettinger 1999; Light 2001; Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner 2003; Parent 2006) and college transfer patterns (Hilmer 1997; McCormick and Carroll 1997; Hilmer 2000; Light and Strayer 2004) provide additional explanations for why years of school would vary across students. An exhaustive exploration of why S would vary among individuals in a given degree/dropout category is beyond the scope of this study, but we consider a subset of issues that are potentially relevant to the interpretation of our findings.
In Figures 1–2, we abstract entirely from individual heterogeneity in the marginal cost of school. While individual differences in preferences and funding opportunities unquestionably affect who stays in school the longest and who obtains a degree, these factors affect the empirical relationship between S, D, and wages only if they are related to labor market productivity. The key issue for our analysis is that financially constrained students are the most likely to accumulate in-school employment experience, which has been shown in some studies (Ruhm 1997; Light 2001) to have a direct effect on postschool earnings. Thus, variation in S among individuals with a given degree status might reflect not only variation in ability, as assumed by our model, but variation in in-school experience as well. In estimating our wage models, we include detailed measures of both in-school and postschool work experience. This enables us to assess the (degree-specific) effect of S on log-wages net of the effect of work experience.
By assuming that skill (KD) is identical among degree holders, we also abstract from the fact that school characteristics and programs of study can affect how much is learned, conditional on student ability or time spent in school; an extensive literature explores the effects of school quality and college major on subsequent earnings (Brewer, Eide, and Ehrenberg 1999; Dale and Krueger 2002; Arcidiacono 2004; Altonji, Elder, and Taber 2005). A related issue is that college quality can affect S if, for example, students at resource-constrained colleges are forced to delay their degree completion because of enrollment limits in courses needed to graduate. This phenomenon is shown by Bound, Lovenheim, and Turner (2007) and Bound and Turner (2007) to be an important determinant of secular increases in time to college degree completion, and it can potentially affect cross-sectional variation in S as well. Of course, resource squeezes on some college campuses cannot explain variation in S among high school graduates as well as college graduates, nor can it explain why S is wage enhancing among college dropouts. Nonetheless, we acknowledge that for college graduates, S can be negatively correlated with college quality as well as individual ability.
Our theoretical framework also makes the simplifying assumption that individuals face no uncertainty about their own abilities. Although this assumption is imposed more often than not in the schooling literature, uncertainty is worth discussing because it has been invoked by Chiswick (1973) and Lange and Topel (2006) to explain how degree effects could arise in the absence of job market signaling or lumpiness in skill acquisition. The argument is that individuals discover their true ability over time, and that the least able drop out of school in response to this discovery while the more able—who learn more than the less able during every year of school—remain in school to complete the degree. We acknowledge that individuals may discover their true ability while in school and that the degree effects that we estimate in Section V might reflect this type of selection-on-ability in addition to lumpiness in learning.6 However, neither of these existing studies helps us understand why S and D vary independently, or why the relationship between S and ability differs for graduates and dropouts.
III. Econometric strategy
In Section II, we assumed that each individual chooses his years of school (S) to maximize acquired skill (K) which, in conjunction with innate ability (A), determines his postschool starting wage. Employers cannot observe K and A directly, but they can observe degree status and S. Thus, the prediction that emerges from our theoretical model is that wages increase with S among dropouts and decrease with S among graduates, because S is associated with higher ability among dropouts and lower ability among graduates.
To assess this prediction, we specify a wage function that allows log-wages to evolve with experience, and schooling attainment to affect the intercept (but not the experience slope) of the experience-earnings path (Mincer 1974). Our theoretical discussion calls for a functional form that allows the intercept of the log-wage path to increase with each successive degree category and to change with years of schooling within each category. Thus, we specify the following wage function:
(2)
where Yi is the natural logarithm of the average hourly wage for individual i, Dki is a vector of dummy variables identifying degree categories, Si is time in school, Zi is a vector of additional covariates (cumulative labor market experience and its square and dummies identifying race and gender), and ui represents unobserved factors. In contrast to the simplifying assumption made in Section II that workers earn a single degree upon reaching a given skill threshold, we now allow for two successive degrees. Specifically, Dk distinguishes between high school dropouts (D1), high school graduates (D2), college dropouts (D3), and college graduates (D4).7 Our model predicts that log-wages increase monotonically with each successive degree (α1 < α2 < α3 < α4), and that the effect of S on these degree effects is positive for dropouts (δ1 > 0, δ3 > 0) and negative for degree holders (δ2 < 0, δ4 < 0).
It is worth reiterating that our specification is not generally used in the degree effects literature. The orthodox approach—often dictated by a lack of independent data on S and D—is to use a spline function or step function in S and omit separate measures of D (Hungerford and Solon 1987; Belman and Heywood 1991). Among studies that control for both S and D, most include degree dummies and an independent (noninteracted) function of S (Frazis 1993; Jaeger and Page 1996; Arkes 1999; Park 1999; Ferrer and Riddell 2002). This is equivalent to imposing the restriction δ1=δ2=δ3=δ4, although some studies relax our restriction that Y is a linear function of S. Jaeger and Page (1996) and Park (1999) propose alternative specifications that allow for interactions between S and D, but they use an extremely flexible functional form that includes a parameter for every year-of-schooling/degree combination. We propose Equation 2 as the most parsimonious way to capture the D–S-specific intercepts that are consistent with our schooling model.
Our goal is not to identify the causal effect of schooling on log-wages, but to assess the signs of the degree-specific schooling slopes unconditional on innate ability. As long as S, D and Z are known to employers and are reasonable proxies for productivity, we can use ordinary least squares (OLS) to estimated the parameters in Equation 2. While we maintain these assumptions, we cannot assume that our survey data are reported without error. Unfortunately, the instrumental variables and generalized method of moments estimators that are often used to account for measurement error in S or D (Ashenfelter and Krueger 1994; Kane, Rouse, and Staiger 1999; Black, Berger, and Scott 2000; Flores-Lagunes and Light 2006) are inappropriate for our application because they allow only one covariate to be reported with error, and they require two, independent reports for the error-ridden variable.8 In the absence of a tractable estimation strategy that accounts for measurement error in both S and D, we compare estimates from our primary sample to those from an alternative sample of seemingly “clean” responses to determine whether our results are sensitive to the inclusion of seemingly erroneous data.9
The notation used in Equation 2 implies that we use cross-sectional data for estimation and, in fact, a cross-section composed of each individual’s postschool starting wage is our primary sample. We also use a panel sample consisting of annual wages reported by each sample member from school exit to the end of the observation period. Regardless of which sample is used, we fit the same lifecycle wage path and identify the same S–D-specific intercepts; the “all wages” sample simply adds observations beyond the first year (or so) of experience, and potentially enhances the precision of all parameter estimates. However, a disadvantage of the “all wages” sample is that estimates of αk and δk will be biased if unobserved factors affecting later wages (for example, employer learning and/or on-the-job training) are related to S and D. We present estimates based on the “all wages” sample for comparison, but prefer the cross-sectional sample of starting wages. We use ordinary least squares to estimate the models with both samples, but when using the panel (“all wages”) sample we correct the standard errors for nonindependence across observations for a given worker. All models are estimated after transforming the data into deviations from sample-specific grand means. We describe each sample in Section IV.
IV. Data
A. Sample Selection and Variable Definitions
We use data from the 1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY79) to estimate the wage functions described in Section III. The NLSY79 began in 1979 with a sample of 12,686 youth born in 1957–64, and it remains in progress today. Respondents were interviewed annually from 1979 to 1994 and biennially thereafter; 2004 is the last year for which data were available when we carried out the analysis. The NLSY79 is an ideal source of data for our analysis because respondents report their highest grade completed, dates of enrollment, and degree attainment; the survey also provides unusually detailed information on labor market activities, which enables us to net out the potentially confounding effects of work experience gained while in school.
The first step in our data creation process is to identify each respondent’s chronological sequence of diplomas and degrees received, along with the date when each credential was awarded. If an individual attended high school, college, or graduate school without earning a diploma or degree, we include his attendance spell and dropout date in the degree sequence. To construct this sequence, we use the following self-reported information: (i) whether the respondent holds a high school diploma or has passed the general educational development test (GED) at the date of the interview and, if so, the month and year of diploma/GED attainment; (ii) whether the respondent is enrolled in school at the time of the interview and, if not, the month and year of his last enrollment; (iii) the respondent’s enrollment status in every month since the last interview; (iv) the month/year the respondent last attended his first, second, and third most recent colleges; and (v) the type and month/year of receipt of as many as three diplomas and degrees or, in earlier survey years, of the highest degree.10 When identical diplomas or degrees are reported multiple times, we generally use the first-reported date; we resort to subsequently reported dates or to the enrollment timelines when information is missing.
We use this information to place each respondent into one of five categories: high school dropout, high school graduate, college dropout, college graduate (bachelor’s degree recipient) or graduate degree recipient. Those respondents who complete their schooling without interruption are classified according to their final degree or dropout status. When individuals receive their schooling discontinuously, we assign them the dropout/degree status that prevails the first time they leave school for at least 18 months. Only 6 percent of respondents change their degree status between this 18-month school exit and their last school exit, so our estimates are not affected by which school exit date is used as long as we control for work experience gained during the interim. We are limited in our ability to form postbachelor’s degree categories because our theoretical model assumes that individuals holding a given degree are homogeneous with respect to acquired skill, and we lack the sample size to define separate categories for holders of master’s, professional, and doctoral degrees. In addition, we are unable to identify the degree programs being pursued by graduate school dropouts. Thus, we combine all graduate degree holders—who make up 2.7 percent of the sample—into a single category (D5), but we do not include interactions between D5 and S in our wage model. Graduate school dropouts remain in our sample as college graduates if they are nonenrolled for at least 18 months between college and graduate school, and report a wage during the interim. As we demonstrate in Section V, our findings are unaffected by whether we categorize graduate students in this fashion, or eliminate them from the sample altogether; additional, unreported experiments, such as moving graduate school dropouts into a sixth category and adding interactions between S and the postcollege degree categories also proved not to affect our inferences.
We choose not to segment the college dropout category into two-year college dropouts, two-year college graduates, and four-year college dropouts because these groups are conceptually indistinct, given the frequent use of two-year colleges as stepping stones to four-year colleges (Rouse 1995; Hilmer 1997; Light and Strayer 2004). For example, we would hesitate to argue that a student who earns an associate’s degree in two years and then spends one year at a four-year college differs in ability from a student who enrolls at a four-year college for three years. We substantiate this decision in Section V by demonstrating that eliminating two-year degree holders from the sample does not significantly affect our estimates. We also show that our inferences do not depend on whether we treat individuals with a GED as high school dropouts (our default classification) or high school graduates.
After classifying each sample member with respect to highest degree, the second step in our data creation process is to identify the corresponding years of school. During each interview, respondents are asked to report their current highest grade completed if they have attended school since the last interview. We use the value reported during the first interview after the degree or dropout date as one measure of time in school, which we now refer to as S1. As an alternative measure of time in school, we use the degree or dropout date in conjunction with the respondent’s birth date to determine the age (measured to the nearest month) at which he or she left school; we refer to this variable as S2.
The degree or dropout date used to define S2 also serves as the career start date. With this date in hand, the next step in our data creation process is to select alternative samples of postschool wages. Our cross-sectional starting wage sample uses the first wage reported after the degree is awarded or the individual drops out of school. Our “all wages” sample includes that same wage, plus a maximum of one wage per year reported by the individual over the remainder of the panel, which ends when he reenrolls in school or is last observed. Given our strategy of allowing the intercept of the age-earning profile to depend on an individual’s S–D combination, each wage sample has its own advantage. The “all wages” sample provides more data with which to fit the log-wage path. The starting wage sample contains relatively little variation in postschool work experience, which minimizes the possibility that D and S are correlated with unmeasured components of work experience due, perhaps, to the most able workers investing more intensively in on-the-job training than less able workers.
The final step in our data creation process is to define the remaining variables. Our dependent variable is the log of the average hourly wage, divided by the consumer price index (CPI-U). In addition to the time-invariant variables D and S (that is, S1 or S2), we include dummy variables identifying male, black, and Hispanic sample members; the default racial/ethnic category is individuals who are nonblack, non-Hispanic. The time-varying covariates include a set of dummy variables indicating the calendar year during which the wage is earned. We use the detailed work history information available in the NLSY79 to construct a measure of cumulative weeks worked from the eighteenth birthday to the date when the wage is earned. In addition, we use the work experience reported by 16- and 17-year-olds (available for respondents who are younger than 18 when the survey begins) to compute average work effort at age 16–17 as a fraction of work effort at age 18, by sex, race/ethnicity, and degree status. We then use these averages to assign every sample member a measure of predicted, early experience. We control for actual experience since age 18 and its square, along with predicted early (younger than age 18) experience in each of our wage models.
Our starting wage sample consists of a single observation for each of 11,712 individuals. While the original NLSY79 sample has 12,686 respondents, we eliminate 313 individuals for whom degree status, degree/dropout dates, and/or highest grade completed cannot be determined. We eliminate another 661 individuals because a postschool wage is not reported. The “all wages” sample contains between one and 21 observations for the same 11,712 individuals, for a total of 126,019 observations.
In addition to analyzing the entire starting wage sample of 11,712 individuals, we also examine a subsample in which schooling and degree variables are judged to be “clean.” To construct this subsample, we exploit the fact that degree attainment and highest grade completed (S1) should conform to certain institutional norms if respondents consider their progress toward a degree when reporting their highest grade completed. We expect high school dropouts to complete grade 11 or lower, high school graduates to complete grade 12, college dropouts to complete at least grade 12 but less than grade 16, and college graduates to complete grade 16. In forming a “clean” sample, we eliminate individuals if their reported S1–D combination is sufficiently far from these expectations: We require S1 ≤ 12, S1=11–13, S1=12–16, S1=15–19, and S1 ≥ 16 for individuals in the high school dropout, high school graduate, college dropout, college graduate, and graduate degree categories, respectively. This strategy eliminates roughly 3 percent of observations in each high school and college category, and 1.3 percent of the graduate degree holders. The remaining sample consists of 11,277 individuals for whom the S1 and D data are invariably less error-ridden than the data in the larger sample. By comparing estimates for our two samples, we can assess the effect of measurement error on the estimates.11 We do not construct a similar “clean” sample using our alternative variable S2 (age at school exit) because parttime and discontinuous enrollment often delay school exit. We control for these delays by including detailed experience measures in our wage model, but we lack clear expectations of the unconditional relationship between age at school exit and degree attainment.
B. Summary Statistics
Table 1 reports summary statistics for the variables used to estimate wage models for both the starting wage and “all wages” samples. Table 2 contains a cross-tabulation of highest grade completed (S1) and degree status (D). It is clear from these distributions that S1 varies considerably within D category. A comparison of the coefficient of variation across columns reveals that S1 varies far more within each dropout category than within each degree category; this conforms to the notion that S1 measures progress made toward a degree and is therefore relatively homogenous among degree holders. However, if we instead ask how often S1 falls within the expected range for that particular degree category (less than 12 for high school dropouts, 12 for high school graduates, 12–15 for college dropouts, 16 for college graduates, and more than 16 for graduate degree holders) we find the most noise among the graduates: S1 is as expected for 97 percent of high school dropouts and 94 percent of college dropouts, but only 85 percent of high school graduates and 79 percent of college graduates. These patterns suggest that there is ample variation with which to identify independent wage effects of S1 within each degree category.
Summary Statistics for Selected Variables
Highest Grade Completed by Highest Degree Received
Table 3 replicates Table 2, except we now use age at school exit (S2) in place of highest grade completed. Using the coefficients of variation for comparison, it is clear that this alternative measure of time in school varies far more within degree category than does highest grade completed. While there is no expected age at which individuals complete each degree category, given that school exit dates can be extended by parttime or interrupted enrollment, it is interesting to note that only 86 percent of high school dropouts leave school by age 18, only 53 percent of high school graduates earn their degrees at age 18, and only 32 percent of college graduates earn their degrees at age 22. In short, age at school exit diverges from S1 + 6 as degree attainment increases. The estimates presented in Section V will reveal whether the marginal wage effects of S1 and S2 differ once we condition on the in-school work experience that explains much of the divergence in these two measures.
Age at School Exit by Highest Degree Received
V. Findings
Table 4 presents estimates of the degree-specific intercepts (αk) and D–S interaction terms (δk) for a variety of wage model specifications, all of which use highest grade completed (S1) as our measure of time in school; additional parameter estimates for each specification are in Table A1. We discuss these estimates before turning to the corresponding estimates in Tables 5 and A1 in which S1 is replaced with age at school exit (S2).
OLS Estimates of Alternative Wage Models Using Highest Grade Completed as Measure of Time in School
Column 1 of Table 4 reports OLS estimates of a model that restricts the four degree-specific schooling coefficients to be equal. The Column 1 specification is representative of much of the existing literature (Frazis 1993; Jaeger and Page 1996; Arkes 1999; Ferrer and Riddell 2002) in which the goal is simply to identify degree effects conditional on S1. Based on the Column 1 estimates, we would predict that the gap in log wages between high school graduates and high school dropouts is 0.005 (0.196–0.191), the corresponding gap among college graduates and dropouts is 0.16 (0.462–0.301), and an additional year of school is associated with a 2 percent wage boost for all workers.12 When we allow the relationship between S1 and log wages to vary across degree categories (Column 2), we estimate a much larger college degree effect than what is seen in Column 1 (0.30 versus 0.16), and we reject at a 1 percent significance level the null hypothesis that the estimated S1 effects are equal across degree categories.
Moreover, the estimates in Column 2 provide support for our theoretical argument that wages increase (decrease) with time in school among dropouts (graduates). The estimated D–S coefficients are 0.019 and 0.039 for the high school and college dropout categories, respectively, and an imprecisely estimated −0.002 and −0.015 for the corresponding graduates categories. These point estimates are consistent with the notion that time in school is positively correlated with ability for dropouts but negatively correlated with ability for degree holders. For the two degree categories, the imprecision of the estimated interaction terms is consistent with the evidence (Table 2) that S1 varies less for graduates than for dropouts. Although the existing variation produces parameter estimates with the predicted signs, we believe highest grade completed is not the preferred measure of time in school for degree holders.
In Columns 3–5 of Table 4, we assess the effects on our OLS estimates of reclassifying certain degree types. In Column 3, we move GED recipients from the high school dropout category to the high school graduate category. This increases the predicted log-wage gap associated with earning a high school degree but has relatively little effect on the estimated interaction effects. The estimated coefficient for the interaction between S1 and D2 reverses sign, but continues to be statistically insignificant. In Column 4, we eliminate two-year degree holders from the sample rather than include them in the college dropout category. Eliminating these relatively high wage earners leads to a decrease in the estimated S1 coefficient for college dropouts, but does not qualitatively affect our findings. In Column 5, we eliminate individuals with postcollege schooling from the sample. Again, this does not alter our inferences regarding the estimated effects of S1 within each degree category.
Our next task is to assess the effects of measurement error on our estimates. In Column 6 of Table 4, we report estimates based on a “clean” sample that excludes observations where the reported S–D combination is highly implausible (for example, no high school diploma but S1=16, or S1=12 and a bachelor’s degree). The differences between these estimates and the corresponding estimates in Column 2 are not significantly different from zero. Despite the fact that the standard errors increase (as expected) when we switch to the clean sample, the estimated S1 coefficients associated with the two degree categories actually become larger in absolute value. The “clean” estimates are consistent with the predictions of our model and with the notion that measurement error in S and D is relatively unimportant.
The final column of estimates in Table 4 is based on our “all wages” sample. We maintain our original degree classifications and include seemingly error-ridden observations in this sample, so the Column 7 estimates should be compared to the estimates shown in Column 2. Qualitatively, the Column 7 estimates substantiate the evidence seen in Column 2: Predicted log-wages increase with each successive degree category and increase (decrease) with each additional year of school for dropouts (graduates). Quantitatively, all four estimated coefficients for the S1–D interactions are slightly larger in absolute value when we use the “all wages” sample than when we rely on the cross-sectional sample, although the college dropout category is the only one for which we reject the null hypothesis of pair-wise equality across models.13 This comparison suggests that S might be weakly, positively correlated with unobserved factors that increase log-wages as the career unfolds. Such a correlation could arise for at least two reasons. First, although we assume employers use D and S to discern worker productivity at the outset of the career, they may not completely learn their workers’ true abilities for a few years, at which point they further reward the high-S (high ability) individuals. Altonji and Pierret (2001) and Lange (2007) provide evidence of this form of employer learning. Second, high-S (high ability) workers might gain work experience that is not captured by our cumulative experience variable, or simply receive higher returns to on-the-job training. Because we do not allow the experience paths to differ across S–D categories, such fanning out on the basis of ability would be subsumed by our estimated intercepts. In general, however, a switch to the “all wages” sample produces only minor changes to the point estimates, and does not significantly affect our key findings.
Next, we ask how our estimates change when we replace highest grade completed (S1) with age at school exit (S2) as our measure of time in school. Table 5 contains estimates for wage models that use this alternative measure, but are otherwise identical to the corresponding specifications in Columns 1–5 and 7 of Table 4; the Column 6 estimates are omitted from Table 5 because we lack priors on the unconditional relationship between degree and age at school exit needed to select a “clean” sample.
OLS Estimates of Alternative Wage Models Using Age at School Exit as Measure of Time in School
In comparing the estimates shown in Columns 1 and 2 of Table 5, we again reject at a 1 percent significance level the equal slope restriction imposed by Specification 1. Using the preferred Specification 2, we find that replacing highest grade completed with age at school exit has little effect on the estimated degree effects, although we now predict a slightly larger wage gap between college dropouts and high school graduates than what is seen in Table 4. However, switching schooling measures has a significant effect on the estimated coefficients for the S–D interactions. In Column 2 of Table 4, we saw that the estimated S1 coefficient is positive (and significant) for dropouts and negative (but insignificant) for graduates. The parameter estimates have the same signs in Table 5, but now the estimated coefficients for both dropout categories are essentially zero (0.002–0.003 with standard errors at least as large as the parameter estimates) while the estimated coefficients for the two degree categories are precisely estimated and, in the case of high school graduates, larger in absolute value (−0.019 versus −0.002 in Table 4).14 The estimates change very little when we reclassify GED recipients as high school graduates (Column 3), eliminate two-year degree holders (Column 4), or drop individuals with postcollege schooling (Column 5). When we switch to the “all wages” sample (Specification 7), the estimated effect of S2 continues to be zero for the two dropout categories, but becomes larger in absolute value for the two degree categories—although, using conventional significance levels, we reject the null hypothesis of equality across models for the college graduate category only.
To understand why our estimates are sensitive to the manner in which we measure time in school, it is useful to consider the two degree categories (high school and college graduates) separately from the two dropout categories. Even if holders of a given degree do not have identical levels of acquired skill, as assumed by our theoretical model, they complete similar programs and earn a similar number of credits. Consider one individual who earns a high school diploma at age 18, and another who earns the same diploma a year earlier. Both should report their highest grade completed as 12 to reflect the fact that they completed the final year of their program, but their reported school exit dates should differ because one of them completed the program more quickly than the other. In short, age at school exit is a more informative measure of what we wish to know about degree recipients—namely, the speed with which they complete a common grade or degree program. Therefore, it comes as no surprise that the estimated S2 slopes in Table 5 (based on age at school exit) predict that degree holders earn approximately 2 percent less (for high school graduates) and 1–2 percent less (for college graduates) for every extra year they take to graduate, whereas the corresponding estimates in Table 4 (based on highest grade completed) lack statistical significance.
In contrast, we believe highest grade completed is a more informative measure than age at school exit for both dropout categories. Our goal is to measure the amount of school completed (that is, credits earned) in order to control for heterogeneity in skill among individuals with a given nondegree status. If reported accurately, highest grade completed is likely to be the preferred measure of schooling attainment for this purpose, given that future dropouts may “drag out” the time to school exit by failing courses, being truant, and otherwise spending time neither learning nor acquiring work experience. We believe the estimated slope coefficients in Table 4, which imply that high school (college) dropouts earn 2–3 percent (3–5 percent) more for every year spent in school, are preferred for assessing the effects of time spent in school among these individuals.
We can offer additional evidence to substantiate the argument that age at school exit is the preferred measure for degree holders in the sense that it measures (inverse) innate ability, whereas highest grade completed is the preferred measure of skill and ability among dropouts. In 1980, over 90 percent of NLSY79 respondents completed the Armed Services Vocational Aptitude Battery (ASVAB). NLSY79 users have access not only to individual ASVAB scores, but also to scores for the Armed Forces Qualification Test (AFQT), which are computed from respondents’ scores on four parts of the ASVAB (word knowledge, paragraph comprehension, arithmetic reasoning, and mathematics knowledge). Because AFQT scores are considered to be good measures of premarket skills (Neal and Johnson 1996), we assess their correlation with both measures of time spent in school for each degree-specific subsample.15 Among individuals in both degree categories, age-adjusted AFQT scores are strongly, negatively correlated with age at school exit but not with highest grade completed. Within both dropout categories, age-adjusted AFQT scores are strongly, positively correlated with highest grade completed, whereas the correlations with age at school exit are small and negative for college school dropouts and zero for high school dropouts.
VI. Concluding Comments
Our analysis begins with the observation that researchers often identify degree effects by controlling for both degree attainment (D) and years of schooling (S) in a wage model without considering why these two measures of schooling attainment would vary independently. We argue that individuals with a given degree are roughly homogenous with respect to acquired skill, but because the more able can earn their degrees relatively quickly, S is negatively correlated with innate ability among this population. Conversely, individuals who drop out of a given degree program vary considerably with respect to both innate ability and acquired skill, and S is positively correlated with these traits. Our simple extension of Card’s (1995, 1999) schooling model justifies the inclusion of both D and S in a wage model, and suggests that the effect of schooling on log-wages should be allowed to differ across degree categories.
In estimating wage models that control for both D and S using data from the 1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, we identify a number of patterns that are consistent with our model. First, we find that the data resoundingly reject the restriction that the effect of years of school on log-wages is equal across degree categories—in other words, it is important to include degree dummies (D) and S–D interactions, rather than simply controlling for S and D. Second, our estimates indicate that additional time in school is associated with higher wages for high school dropouts and college dropouts, but with lower wages for high school graduates and college graduates. Third, schooling effects for the two dropout categories are estimated more precisely when we use highest grade completed as the measure of S than when we use age at school exit. For the two graduate categories, the opposite is true. Fourth, our estimates prove to be largely invariant to our attempts to account for measurement error in self-reported S and D, which suggests that the independent variation in these two dimensions of schooling attainment is not dominated by “noise.”
The fact that our alternative measures of time spent in school (age at school exit and highest grade completed) appear to capture different information for degree holders and dropouts is a useful finding in its own right. We argue that high school and college graduates are expected to complete grades 12 and 16, respectively, and that, as a result, the age at which they earn their degrees is a more informative measure of ability than is their highest grade completed. Conversely, highest grade completed is a useful measure of progress made toward a degree among dropouts, whereas variation in age at school exit might reflect time spent neither gaining work experience (which we are able to control for separately) nor learning. Our estimates suggest that individuals within a given degree or dropout category vary considerably with respect to their ability and/or acquired skill, and that additional measures of schooling attainment are useful for explaining variation in postschool wages. While ours is not the first study to view schooling attainment as a multidimensional construct, we suspect there is far more to be learned by exploring heterogeneity in completion patterns among individuals with a given level of schooling attainment.
Appendix 1
Footnotes
Alfonso Flores-Lagunes is an assistant professor of food and resource economics at the University of Florida and a research fellow at IZA. Audrey Light is a professor of economics at Ohio State University. The authors thank Lung-fei Lee and Ian Walker for useful discussions, Stephen Bronars for comments on an earlier draft, and Alex Shcherbakov for providing excellent research assistance. Alfonso Flores-Lagunes gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Industrial Relations Section at Princeton University. The data used in this article can be obtained beginning six months after publication through three years hence from Audrey Light, Department of Economics, 410 Arps Hall, 1945 N. High Street, Columbus, OH 43210; light.20{at}osu.edu.
↵1. Following Weiss (1995), we use the term sorting to refer to both signaling and screening versions of the models.
↵2. In other models (for example, Becker 1964; Arrow 1973; Spence 1973; Stiglitz 1973; Card 1999) schooling attainment is a one-dimensional construct; whether it is measured as highest grade completed or highest degree received is left to survey designers and data analysts.
↵3. In fact, existing estimates appear to be highly sensitive to functional form. When controlling for (non interacted) dummy variables for each degree level and each year of schooling, Jaeger and Page (1996) predict a gap in log wages of 0.16 between bachelor’s degree holders and college dropouts. When controlling for dummy variables for every S–D cell, they predict the same gap in log wages (holding S constant at 16) to be 75 percent higher.
↵4. We assume, as does Card (1995, 1999), that agents do not choose their optimal schooling level with an eye toward possible interactions between schooling attainment and postschool skill investments. Thus, they focus on the skill (and wages) that will potentially prevail at the outset of the career.
↵5. Point c′ in Figure 3 corresponds to staying in school beyond the single degree program that we assume is available. Clearly, we could extend our framework to include a higher degree, in which case the production function would contain another discontinuity at a skill level beyond KD; point c′ would then correspond to dropping out of this higher degree program.
↵6. The degree effects that we estimate also can reflect job market signaling. In fact, students might use both degree attainment and speed of completion as a multidimensional signal of their ability, as suggested by Groot and Oosterbeek (1994). In light of recent evidence (Lange 2007) that employers learn workers’ true ability quite quickly—and that, as a result, signaling appears to play a relatively minor role—we focus on a strictly human capital explanation for the patterns seen in the data.
↵7. The sample used to estimate Equation 2 includes individuals who proceed beyond a college (bachelor’s) degree to attend a wide variety of graduate programs. We experiment with combining these individuals into a fifth (and sixth) degree category and, alternatively, dropping them from the sample. We discuss these issues, as well as other issues related to our degree categories, in Section IV.
↵8. We have an independent report of high school graduation status for a subset of respondents for whom high school transcripts were collected, but the NLSY79 does not provide similar validation data for college attendance and degrees. Similarly, we have sibling-reported highest grade completed for respondents with in-sample siblings, but these reports predate final schooling attainment for many respondents.
↵9. A potentially useful method for addressing measurement error in a categorical variable such as D is the Lee and Porter (1984) switching regression model with imperfect regime (degree) classification. We also extend this model to our application, and find no evidence that degree reporting errors have an important effect on the estimates reported in Section V.
↵10. Monthly enrollment status questions (Item iii) were asked in every interview except the first, and questions about degree types and dates (Item v) were asked every year except 1985–87. All other questions were asked in every survey year, although many were only asked of respondents who indicated via a leadin question that they had attended school since the last interview.
↵11. Our strategy is less demanding of the data than those requiring validation data (for example, Freeman 1984), and more flexible than those requiring relatively simple functional forms in order to jointly estimate measurement error and outcome models (Kane, Rouse, and Staiger 1999; Black, Berger, and Scott 2000; Flores-Lagunes and Light 2006).
↵12. When we reestimate the model after dropping blacks and Hispanics from the sample, the difference in predicted log-wage for high school dropouts and high school graduates increases to 0.054. We do not report additional findings based on a sample of whites because they are very similar to what is shown in Tables 4–5 in all other respects.
↵13. Proceeding in order from D1 to D4, the p-values for the tests of pair-wise equality across models are 0.21, 0.21, 0.02, and 0.66.
↵14. We estimated a modified Column 2 specification that includes both S1–D and S2–D interactions. The coefficients for these eight interaction terms are virtually identical to those reported in Column 2 of Tables 4–5, except the imprecisely estimated coefficients (S1–D2, S1–D4, S2–D1, and S2–D3) generally move closer to zero in magnitude.
↵15. Respondents’ ages ranged from 16 to 23 when the ASVAB was administered in 1980, so we use deviations between raw scores and age-specific means.
- Received August 2008.
- Accepted February 2009.