Abstract
With data from the Assets and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old Survey, we estimate dynamic models of three dimensions of families’ eldercare arrangements: the use of each potential care arrangement, namely care provided by a spouse, care provided by an adult child, formal home healthcare, and/or institutional care; the selection of the primary care arrangement; and hours in each care arrangement. Our results indicate that both observed heterogeneity and positive true state dependence contribute to the persistence of care arrangements. Evidence of positive true state dependence for most or all modes of care in all models suggests that inertia generally dominates caregiver burnout. Our results indicate that formal care decisions depend on the cost and quality of care. As a result of inertia, the effectiveness of long-term care policy depends on timing: initial caregiving decisions are more sensitive than subsequent decisions to economic incentives.
I. Introduction
In light of population aging and high disability rates among the elderly (Butler 1997; Spillman and Long 2007), many families face decisions concerning longterm care arrangements for disabled elderly relatives. With the assistance of family members, most notably spouses and adult children, many disabled elderly individuals remain in the community (Shirey and Summer 2000). Others rely exclusively on formal home healthcare or a combination of formal home healthcare and informal care provided by relatives and friends (Mack and Thompson 2005). Institutional care represents another major source of care for this population (Burwell and Jackson 1994; Family Caregiver Alliance 2015).
Long-term care arrangements have profound economic, social, and psychological implications.Komisar and Thompson (2007) report that national spending on long-term care for elderly and disabled individuals exceeded $200 billion in 2005. Medicaid and Medicare respectively covered approximately 49 and 20 percent of these expenses, while private health and long-term care insurance covered roughly seven percent. Individuals and their families financed about 18 percent of long-term care services, while the remaining 5 percent was financed by other private and public sources (Komisar and Thompson 2007). Most informal care provided by family members is unpaid, but the opportunity costs in terms of foregone earnings, household production, human capital accumulation (Skira 2015), and leisure are often substantial. Moreover, the provision of informal care can be psychologically burdensome for caregivers (Martin 2000; Byrne et al. 2009), and institutional care often entails high social and psychological costs for elderly individuals (Macken 1986; Pezzin, Kemper, and Reschovsky 1996; Coe and Van Houtven 2009).
The aging of the population and the profound implications of care arrangements for elderly individuals, their families, and society highlight the importance of developing appropriate public policies concerning long-term care arrangements for the elderly. Although an extensive literature examines families’ long-term care decisions, most studies neglect the intertemporal dimensions of care. Using data from five waves of the Assets and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old Survey collected between 1995 and 2004, we contribute to the long-term care literature by developing and estimating three dynamic models of families’ eldercare arrangements. These models distinguish among care provided by a spouse, care provided by an adult child or childin- law, formal home healthcare, and institutional care, while also allowing for the possibility that the elderly individual remains independent.
The modeling and estimation of dynamic models of long-term care is still in its infancy.1 Even the modeling and estimation of family decision-making in a dynamic environment is relatively new. This paper explores five issues associated with modeling and estimation of dynamic models of long-term care with the purpose of helping future researchers make informed decisions about modeling and policy. First, our models capture several dimensions of families’ care arrangements that appear in the literature, namely the use of each potential care arrangement (for example, Pezzin and Schone 1999a; Aykan 2002; Heitmueller and Michaud 2006; Grabowski and Gruber 2007; Skira 2015), the selection of the primary care arrangement (for example, Stern 1995; Hoerger, Picone, and Sloan 1996; Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Engers and Stern 2002; Rainer and Siedler 2009; Skira 2015), and hours in each potential care arrangement (for example, Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger 1997; Checkovich and Stern 2002; Van Houtven and Norton 2004; Brown 2006; Stabile, Laporte, and Coyte 2006; Pezzin, Pollak, and Schone 2007; Byrne et al. 2009). We estimate these three dimensions of care arrangements separately because (i) most of the literature considers only one dimension of informal care (for example, the selection of the primary caregiver) and (ii) we want to understand each dimension of informal care provision before allowing for strategic interactions as in Byrne et al. (2009). Second, our dynamic framework links care arrangements over time by allowing for state dependence (in effect, persistence in care arrangements) while distinguishing between spurious state dependence due to observed and unobserved heterogeneity and true state dependence due to inertia or caregiver burnout. To capture the possibility of inertia, our models allow for positive true state dependence.2 For example, our models distinguish between persistence in care arrangements attributable to a family’s preferences (for example, an aversion to institutional care) and true state dependence stemming from the high costs of transitioning from one care arrangement to another (for example, into or out of institutional care). Third, we evaluate the costs and benefits of using different measures of individual wealth and income in an environment where wealth is measured with significant measurement error over time and missing income data reflect selection bias. Fourth, we quantify geographic mobility with particular emphasis on evidence of endogeneity. Fifth, we compare estimated policy effects across different models.
Our results indicate that both observed heterogeneity and true state dependence contribute to the persistence of care arrangements, thus highlighting the importance of a framework that links care arrangements over time. Our findings suggest that inertia (positive true state dependence) dominates caregiver burnout and that the use of formal care arrangements depends on the cost and quality of care. Our results provide important policy implications. The effects of market conditions and public policies on the use of formal home healthcare and institutional care are smaller and less statistically significant in our dynamic model than in an otherwise identical static model. This pattern suggests that the measured effects in the dynamic model reflect flows while those in the static model reflect a stock of present and future flows. Thus, the timing of policy aimed at long-term care is crucial because it has a larger effect when the caregiving decision is first made and because this decision exhibits persistence in part due to inertia.
The outline of the paper is as follows. In Section II, we present a brief review of the long-term care literature. In Section III, we describe the data and present descriptive statistics on the frequency of care arrangements and intertemporal patterns of care. In Section IV, we present our estimation methodology, a new approach to controlling for initial conditions according to Heckman (1981), and results of our three dynamic models. We discuss the policy implications of our results in Section V. We present robustness checks and conclude in Sections VI and VII.
II. Literature Review
Although predominantly empirical, the long-term care literature offers several formal economic models. Given the complexities inherent in families’ longterm decisions, none captures all dimensions of decision-making within families. The models vary with respect to the assumptions concerning family members’ preferences, the number of children participating in the decision-making process, and the scope of care decisions considered.
Allowing for the possibility that preferences vary across family members, several papers present game-theoretic models (Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger 1997; Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Pezzin and Schone 1999a; Checkovich and Stern 2002; Engers and Stern 2002; Brown 2006; Pezzin, Pollak, and Schone 2007; Byrne et al. 2009). Other models are based on the assumption of common preferences; for example, Hoerger, Picone, and Sloan (1996) and Stabile, Laporte, and Coyte (2006) rely on the assumption of a single family utility function. In the Kotlikoff and Morris (1990) model, the parent and child solve separate maximization problems if they live separately but maximize a weighted average of their individual utility functions subject to their pooled budget constraint if they live together. In contrast to our previous work (for example, Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Engers and Stern 2002; Byrne et al. 2009), this paper abstracts from the possibility that family members have different preferences concerning care arrangements in order to focus on the dynamic dimension of care.
Several models accommodate all adult children in the decision-making process (Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Checkovich and Stern 2002; Engers and Stern 2002; Van Houtven and Norton 2004; Brown 2006; Byrne et al. 2009). Others simplify modeling and/or estimation by focusing on families that include only one child (Kotlikoff and Morris 1990) or two adult children (Pezzin, Pollak, and Schone 2007) or by assuming that only one child participates in the family’s long-term care decisions (Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger 1997; Pezzin and Schone 1999a; Skira 2015). In this paper, we restrict our sample to families with at most four children, but we treat each child as a potential caregiver.
The models in this literature also vary with respect to the dimension (for example, primary care arrangement) and modes (for example, informal care provided by an adult child) of care decisions examined. Models presented in Hiedemann and Stern (1999) and Engers and Stern (2002) focus on the family’s selection of the primary care arrangement, including informal care provided by an adult child, institutional care, or continued independence. Checkovich and Stern (2002) and Brown (2006) model the quantity of informal care provided by each adult child. Similarly, Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger (1997), Pezzin and Schone (1999a), Stabile, Laporte, and Coyte (2006), and Byrne et al. (2009) model the provision of informal care and formal home healthcare. Stabile, Laporte, and Coyte (2006) distinguish between publicly and privately financed home healthcare. Van Houtven and Norton (2004) model children’s provision of informal care and parents’ use of formal care, defined broadly as nursing home care, home healthcare, hospital care, physician visits, and outpatient surgery. Hoerger, Picone, and Sloan (1996) and Pezzin, Pollak, and Schone (2007) focus on living arrangements of sick or disabled elderly individuals (for example, independent living in the community or residence in an intergenerational household). Distinguishing among care provided by a spouse, care provided by an adult child or child-in-law, formal home healthcare, and institutional care, this paper examines three dimensions of families’ care arrangements: the use of each potential mode of care, the selection of the primary care arrangement, and hours in each arrangement.
Although the provision of eldercare is an inherently dynamic process, most of the literature abstracts from the intertemporal dimensions of care. Exceptions include Börsch-Supan, Kotlikoff, and Morris (1991), Garber and MaCurdy (1990), Dostie and Léger (2005), Heitmueller and Michaud (2006), Gardner and Gilleskie (2012), and Skira (2015). Using a framework that accounts for unobserved heterogeneity and state dependence, Heitmueller and Michaud (2006) explore the causal links between employment and informal care of sick, disabled, or elderly individuals over time. In a dynamic model of savings and Medicaid enrollment decisions, Gardner and Gilleskie (2012) jointly estimate long-term care arrangements, savings/gifting behavior, insurance coverage, and health transitions. Their approach incorporates unobserved permanent and time-varying heterogeneity. Skira (2015) focuses on how care provision by a child affects the human capital accumulation process of that child. The other three studies focus on living arrangements of elderly individuals. Börsch-Supan, Kotlikoff, and Morris (1991) examine transitions among living independently, living with adult children, and living in an institution. Garber and MaCurdy (1990) model transitions from living in the community to residing in a nursing home and vice versa, as well as transitions from one of these two living arrangements to death. Accounting for unobserved heterogeneity as well as state and duration dependence, Dostie and Léger (2005) examine transitions among independent living, cohabitation, nursing home residence, and death.
Following Dostie and Léger (2005), Heitmueller and Michaud (2006), Gardner and Gilleskie (2012), and Skira (2015), our models account for unobserved heterogeneity and state dependence. Distinguishing among four modes of care, our models encompass a broader range of care arrangements than those in the existing literature. Examining three care dimensions of eldercare decisions—the use of each potential mode of care, the selection of the primary care arrangement, and hours in each arrangement, we also provide a richer description of long-term care dynamics.
III. Data
To examine families’ care arrangements over time, we use data from the 1995, 1998, 2000, 2002, and 2004 waves of the Assets and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old (AHEAD)/Health and Retirement (HRS) survey. With an emphasis on the joint dynamics of health and demographic characteristics, this nationally representative longitudinal survey provides a particularly rich source of information concerning long-term care arrangements. Selection criteria for the initial AHEAD/HRS survey, conducted in 1993, include age and living arrangements. In particular, this initial wave contains 6,047 households with noninstitutionalized individuals aged 70 years or older. However, subsequent waves retain all living respondents, thus enabling the study of elderly individuals in the community as well as nursing home residents. Spouses of respondents are also respondents even if they would not otherwise qualify on the basis of their own age, thus increasing the sample size for the initial wave to 8,222 respondents. Although AHEAD/HRS oversamples Florida residents, this oversampling introduces no estimation bias assuming that residential location is exogenous. AHEAD/ HRS also oversamples black and Hispanic households.
After excluding observations with missing values for variables used in our analysis, individuals who participated in only one wave of the survey, individuals who provided inconsistent responses, individuals who married or remarried over the course of the survey, families with more than four children, and mixed-race couples, our sample consists of 3,353 individuals, including spouses of original respondents. In addition to 914 married couples (where each individual represents a respondent), the sample includes 267 unmarried men and 1,258 unmarried women. The preponderance of women (nearly two-thirds of the sample) and the higher marriage rates among men (77.4 percent of men compared to 42.1 percent of women) reflect differences in life expectancy by gender and age differences between husbands and wives. Fifty-three percent of elderly households participate in all five waves of the survey.
Our models include characteristics that influence an elderly individual’s caregiving needs, opportunities, and preferences. The need for care may increase with age and activity limitations; accordingly, our models control for the elderly individual’s age, problems with activities of daily living (ADLs), and problems with instrumental activities of daily living (IADLs). The presence of a spouse may reduce an elderly individual’s need for assistance from adult children or from formal care providers, particularly if the spouse is relatively young and healthy; thus, our models control for the elderly individual’s marital status, the spouse’s age, and the spouse’s activity limitations. Since patterns of care may differ for men and women and across white, black, and Hispanic families, our models control for gender as well as race/ethnicity. Moreover, to capture potential differences in care arrangements for mothers/wives relative to fathers/husbands by race and ethnicity (Martin 2000; Hiedemann 2012), each of our models also includes interactions between gender and race/ethnicity.
Assets and income are potentially important characteristics that influence an elderly individual’s caregiving needs and opportunities because the ability to purchase care may reduce an individual’s dependence on relatives. Unfortunately, there are several problems with the asset data reported in AHEAD. The first problemconcerns large, spurious changes in assets within families across time due to changes in the survey structure (for details, see Hurd, Juster, and Smith 2003; Juster et al. 2007). Since transitions are very important in a dynamic model, the large variation in asset changes is problematic. Hill (2006) also finds unreasonable variation in changes in assets in HRS.3 Second, among wealthier individuals, 1993 assets are understated by a factor of two. Third, income and asset reports in the second wave are inconsistent. Fourth, mean assets double between the second and third waves. Fifth, financial measures, particularly those related to equity in a second home, are underreported (Hurd, Juster, and Smith 2003; Juster et al. 2007). Finally, income measures are underreported or misreported (Hurd, Juster, and Smith 2003). In the absence of good asset and income data, our models include the elderly individual’s educational attainment as a proxy for her financial resources.We test whether assets and income, as measured in AHEAD/HRS, affect family decisions and explore how best to use the data by conducting Lagrange Multiplier tests.4
Table 1 displays descriptive statistics for the respondents for the first year of data.5 As a consequence of the exclusion of nursing home residents from the initial wave and the inclusion of spouses regardless of age, the characteristics of our sample differ from those of a random sample of individuals aged 72 years and over.6 Respondents range in age from 49 to 103 years, with a mean of 78 years and a standard deviation of six years. On average, the respondents report difficulty with 0.54 activities of daily living (ADL) such as eating, dressing, or bathing. But the sample exhibits considerable variation with regard to ADL problems. While some individuals report no problems with activities of daily living, others report problems with as many as all six ADLs. Similarly, the respondents report an average of 0.43 problems with instrumental activities of daily living (IADLs), such as using a telephone, taking medication, handling money, shopping, or preparing meals; here too the sample displays considerable variation, with respondents reporting a range of zero to five IADL problems.
Descriptive Statistics for the First Year
In addition to 2,906 individuals (86.7 percent of the sample) who identify as non- Hispanic white, the sample includes 324 individuals (9.7 percent of the sample) who identify as non-Hispanic black and 123 individuals (3.7 percent of the sample) who identify as Hispanic. Although the original sample includes individuals with other racial/ethnic identities, none of these individuals remained in the sample after applying the selection criteria.With respect to education, 33.2 percent of respondents have a high school diploma but not a college degree, and 31.0 percent report having a college or graduate degree.
The elderly households in our sample report a total of 4,489 adult children and 3,318 children-in-law. Since each member of this generation is a potential caregiver, our models include demographic characteristics of the adult children and children-in-law. These characteristics reflect a potential caregiver’s opportunity costs of time, effectiveness in the caregiving role, and/or caregiving burden. Specifically, our models control for the adult child’s or child-in-law’s years of schooling, employment status, marital status, family size (number of children), age, and gender. Despite the potential endogeneity of employment status (see, for example, Ettner 1996), this exploratory analysis abstracts from the younger generation’s employment status in order to focus on the intertemporal dimension of care. In other work (Byrne et al. 2009), we model adult children’s caregiving decisions as part of a broader utility maximization framework that includes hours of work. As discussed extensively in Hiedemann (2012), the role of child gender in eldercare provision may vary by race and ethnicity; thus, our models also interact child gender with race and ethnicity. Finally, coresidence with or proximity to an elderly parent or parent-in-lawmay facilitate care provision. As discussed inKonrad et al. (2002) and Rainer and Seidler (2009), location may be endogenous. However, Johar and Maruyama (2012) and Stern (2014) show that the long-term game described in Konrad et al. (2002) may not be supported by the data, and Stern (1995) shows that, even after controlling for endogeneity, geographical distance explains variation in informal care arrangements. Accordingly, our models include measures of distance and coresidence, and we conduct likelihood ratio tests to infer whether location is endogenous.
As shown in the second panel of Table 1, the younger generation displays near gender balance: 51.1 percent are daughters or daughters-in-law. The average child or child-inlaw is almost 49 years old with nearly 14 years of schooling. These individuals report 29.8 hours of labor market work per week, but this figure understates mean labor market activity because weekly work hours are truncated at 40. On average, the adult children and children-in-law of the elderly respondents have 2.2 children, but it is worth noting that some of these children belong to both a child and a child-in-law. A small proportion (3.3 percent) of the adult children and children-in-law reside with the elderly respondents, and 35.5 percent live within 10 miles of the elderly respondents.
In addition to demographic characteristics and activity limitations, market conditions and public policies may influence families’ care arrangements for elderly individuals. Our models control for several dimensions of the market for formal care in the elderly individual’s or couple’s state of residence: the average weekly cost of full-time home healthcare (16 hours a day for seven days, or 112 hours per week), nursing home staff hours per nursing home resident per day in facilities with Medicare or Medicaid beds, nursing home beds per individual above 70 years, and a measure of the overall level of disability among nursing home residents.As discussed inHarrington, Carrillo, and LaCava (2006), this disability measure (average ADL score) is a composite score that reflects nursing home residents’ needs for assistance with three ADLs, namely eating, toileting, and transferring. Each nursing home resident was assigned a score from one to three for each of these ADLs, increasing in the amount of assistance needed. A summary score ranging from three to nine was compiled for each facility; facility scores were then summarized for each state.7
The market for formal home healthcare and institutional care varies by state. The statistics presented in the third panel describe the market conditions facing elderly households in our sample during the first year of data.8 On average, these households reside in states where the weekly cost of full-time home healthcare ranges from $699 to $1,081, with a mean of $872. These are real costs, deflated with state-specific price deflators (U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis 1999). The elderly households in our sample live in states with 2.4 to 3.6 nursing home staff hours per nursing home resident per day and 2.6 [=100*exp(-3.637)] to 10.3 beds per 100 individuals over 70 years. On average, these households reside in states where the facility score ranges from 5.2 to 6.7 with a mean of 5.8 and a standard deviation of 0.31.
Many households rely on public assistance, most notably Medicaid, to cover their long-term care expenses. Eligibility for Medicaid is linked to actual or potential receipt of cash assistance under the Supplemental Security Income (SSI) program or the former Aid to Families with Dependent Children program. Elderly individuals or couples are eligible for SSI payments if their monthly countable income (income less $20) and countable resources fall belowa certain threshold. Income limits for Medicaid eligibility vary widely by state. Given the lack of state-level data for some years and the high correlation of a state’s income limits across time, our models include only 1993 income limits.9 In most states, individuals or couples whose incomes exceed the limits for Medicaid eligibility qualify for assistance if their medical expenses are high relative to their incomes. States with a medically needy program allow households to deduct medical expenses from income when determining eligibility for Medicaid coverage of nursing home care or formal home healthcare. Thus, our models also control for the presence of a medically needy program.
The bottom panel of Table 1 presents the 1993 average Medicaid income limits facing elderly individuals in our sample as well as the proportion of sampled households residing in states with a medically needy program. Individuals face monthly income limits ranging from $238 to $724, with a mean of $446; couples face monthly income limits ranging from $311 to $1,110, with a mean of $673. More than 95 percent of households in our sample reside in states that had a medically needy program in 1993.
As discussed in more detail later, we present three dynamic models of families’ longterm care decisions. In particular, we model the family’s decision whether to use each potential care arrangement (Section IV.A), the family’s selection of the primary care arrangement (Section IV.E, and hours spent in each care arrangement (Section IV.G). Our models distinguish among several modes of care—institutional care, formal home healthcare, informal care provided by a spouse, and informal care provided by a child or child-in-law—while allowing for the possibility that an elderly individual does not receive any of these modes of care.
Eighty-nine percent of the elderly individuals in our sample receive no care during the first year. Among those relying on at least one mode of care, informal care arrangements are more common than formal care arrangements. More specifically, as shown in Table 2, 7.2 percent of respondents receive care from a spouse, and 5.5 percent receive care from an adult child or child-in-law. While 1.4 percent of respondents rely on formal home healthcare, only 0.9 percent receive nursing home care. Similarly, informal care arrangements are more common than formal arrangements as the primary mode of care.
Spousal caregivers tend to provide substantially more care than do formal home healthcare providers or adult children. On average, during the first year of data, spousal caregivers provide 60.7 hours of care per week. In contrast, the average amount of formal home healthcare is 29.4 hours per week among those who rely on this mode of care. The comparable figure for care provided by adult children or children-in-law is 14.3 hours per week. The correlation between the use of any care and hours of care is high (0.961), but it is statistically significantly different from one. In contrast, the correlations between use of any care or hours of care and the use of a primary caregiver are considerably lower, at 0.284 and 0.038, respectively. Collectively, the magnitudes of these correlations suggest that modeling each dimension of care may yield unique insights concerning families’ care arrangements.
Frequency of Care Mode
Conditioning on using a particular mode of care (for example, spouse), the correlation between the primary care arrangement and hours of care increases substantially for all modes of care except care provided by an adult child; for example, the correlation between the choice of the primary caregiver and hours in care increases from 0.038 overall to 0.806, conditional on the reliance on any spousal care. Conditional on using a particular mode of care, the relatively high correlations between the primary care arrangement (in the case of spousal care and the two modes of formal care) and hours of care imply that the decision to rely on a particular mode of care dominates the decision concerning the amount of care for spousal care and formal care arrangements.
As discussed earlier, we observe each elderly individual in our sample for at least two and at most five different time periods. Table 3 shows the number of observed transitions out of a potential 73,816 transitions into and out of each potential care arrangement. We observe 401 (out of 3,451+ 401 possible) transitions into spousal care (a transition rate of over 10 percent) and 254 transitions out of (289 + 254 possible) spousal care (a transition rate of over 46 percent). Transition rates into nonspousal care arrangements range from just over one percent (child or child-in-law) to just under one percent (institutional care).We observe a transition rate of 26 percent out of institutional care, a rate of almost 43 percent out of care by a particular child or child-in-law care, and a rate of over 67 percent out of formal home care.
Intertemporal Patterns of Care
IV. Dynamic Models of Long-Term Care Arrangements
In most families that include an elderly individual receiving long-term care, one caregiver provides all or nearly all of the care. However, shared caregiving is not uncommon, particularly in large families (Checkovich and Stern 2002). Thus, models of families’ primary care arrangements as well as models that allow for multiple care arrangements offer valuable insights. However, discrete-choice models cannot capture marginal effects within a particular arrangement as discrete-choice models only involve decisions of whether or not the care arrangement was chosen (not the intensity of the choice). Thus, modeling time spent in each care arrangement may be more informative than modeling the discrete dimensions of care. Also, modeling time in each arrangement may reveal rich substitution patterns across modes of care. Unfortunately, however, our data on hours of care are bracketed, and these data probably contain significant measurement error. Given the value of each of these three types of models, we model all three dimensions of families’ care arrangements for an elderly individual in a particular time period: the use of each potential care arrangement, the selection of the primary care arrangement, and the hours spent in each care arrangement. Consistent with most of the literature, we estimate these three dimensions of care separately. Separate models enable us to examine whether time dependence of care arrangements varies across these three dimensions of care. For example, caregiver burnout may be more relevant for the primary caregiver than for other caregivers.
Each of our models distinguishes among several modes of care: institutional care, formal home healthcare, informal care provided by the spouse, and informal care provided by an adult child or child-in-law, while also allowing for the possibility that an elderly individual receives no formal or informal care in a particular period. In each model, the family makes decisions taking into account characteristics of the potential care arrangements. In contrast to our previous work (for example, Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Engers and Stern 2002; Byrne et al. 2009), we abstract from the possibility that family members have different preferences and from details about the decision-making process.
Care arrangements may persist as a result of the family’s preferences or constraints or as a result of inertia. For example, a family’s aversion to institutional care may lead to persistence in care arrangements. Differences across family members with respect to their caregiving effectiveness or their opportunity costs of time may also contribute to persistence in care arrangements. Accordingly, our models control for observable factors as well as several types of unobserved heterogeneity that may lead to persistence in care arrangements (in effect, spurious state dependence). Moreover, the costs of transitioning from one care arrangement to another may enhance the value of the current arrangement. The lifestyle changes required to enable an adult child to provide care or an elderly individual’s attachment to a formal home health aide may lead to inertia in care arrangements. Similarly, moving to a nursing home requires substantial lifestyle changes, as well as disinvestments that may be difficult to reverse, such as selling a home. To capture the possibility of inertia, our models allow for positive true state dependence.
Alternatively, care arrangements may evolve over time as conditions change or as a caregiver experiences burnout. For example, an elderly individual’s care arrangements may evolve as her health or that of her spouse deteriorates, her spouse dies, or formal care becomes more expensive. Accordingly, our models control for relevant timevarying characteristics that may affect a family’s caregiving decisions. Our models also allow the set of potential care arrangements to vary over time in response to changes in family structure. In addition, adult children may rotate the role of primary caregiver (in effect, the caregiver providing the most care) as a way to share the burden or as the caregiver experiences burnout. To allow for the possibility of caregiver burnout, our models allow for negative true state dependence.
We develop and estimate three dynamic models of care. Two of these are discretechoice models, while the third is a continuous choice model with frequent corner solutions. In the Multiple Caregiver Model, the family decides whether to use each potential care arrangement (institutional care, formal home healthcare, care provided by the spouse, and/or care provided by each particular child). This model allows for the possibility that the elderly individual relies on more than one concurrent caregiver or caregiving arrangement. In the Primary Caregiver Model, the family selects the primary care arrangement from among all available alternatives. Finally, in the Hours of Care Model, the family determines hours in each potential care arrangement. Like the Multiple Caregiver Model, this model allows for multiple care arrangements.
In all of our models, we assume that each family has an underlying latent value for each potential care arrangement. More formally, consider family n that consists of one or two elderly individuals, Jn adult children, and up to Jn children-in-law. Elderly individual i (i = father or mother) may require care at time t. If she is married, her spouse may provide some or all of her care. In addition, each adult child or adult child-in-law is a potential caregiver. Depending on the model, the family decides whether to rely on each potential care arrangement, selects the primary care arrangement, or determines how much of each arrangement to use. Define the Jn + 4 caregiving alternatives as: no care, care provided by a spouse, formal home healthcare, care in a nursing home, and informal care from each of the Jn children or their spouses.
The latent value of care alternative j to individual i in family n at time t is denoted by

The vector Xnit includes exogenous characteristics of the elderly individual.10 In particular, Xnit includes demographic characteristics and activity limitations that may influence an elderly individual’s caregiving needs, opportunities, and preferences. The vector Znijt includes exogenous characteristics of the potential care arrangements, namely demographics characteristics of the adult children and children-in-law and market conditions or public policies in the elderly individual’s or household’s state of residence.
The observed variable corresponding to the latent variable is given by ynijt . As discussed in the following subsections, the exact definition of the corresponding observed variable varies with the model specification. The inclusion of ynijt –1 allows past choices to influence the current value of alternative j and thus captures the true dynamic component of long-term care decision-making. To distinguish between true state dependence (as captured by αj) and persistence in care arrangements due to unobserved heterogeneity (in effect, spurious state dependence), we allow for unobserved correlation across time (as captured by ωnijt). The εnijt is an idiosyncratic error with an assumed distribution that varies across models for computational convenience. We refer to αj as true state dependence, which is alternative-specific in our models.
We decompose the nonidiosyncratic portion of the random components of families’ long-term care decisions, ωnijt, into three types of unobserved heterogeneity:

where we assume uni ~iidN(0,1), vnit ~iidN(0,1), and ηnij~iidN(0,ση 2). The δj and λj terms are alternative-specific factor loadings.11 Some elderly individuals may have preferences for certain care options that are not observed to the econometrician and hence not captured by X or Z. For example, a family may avoid institutional care due to a particularly strong philosophical or cultural reason. Such individual/family-alternativespecific correlation across time is captured by ηnij. In addition, there may be individualor family-specific characteristics that influence all care alternatives across time but are unobserved by the econometrician. For example, any unobserved characteristic of the parent that affects the parent’s need for care is captured in uni . Similarly, high levels of wealth may enhance the value of all care alternatives by enabling families to purchase higher-quality formal care and/or to alleviate the burden associated with informal care (for example, by purchasing other time-intensive services such as housekeeping). Finally, vnit allows for individual/time-specific unobserved heterogeneity, such as temporary health conditions unrelated to ADL or IADL limitations. For ease of exposition, we suppress the family subscript in the following subsections.
Two other issues associated with estimating dynamic models are initial conditions and duration dependence.We discuss initial conditions in Section IV.B.12 In this paper, we choose not to model duration dependence because of the limited number of waves in the data. Dostie and Léger (2005) model duration dependence and find negative duration dependence in living arrangements, but they use a much longer panel from the PSID. Other studies, for example, Roth et al. (2001), Gaugler et al. (2005a, 2005b), and Perren, Schmid, and Wettstein (2006), model duration of caregiving, but they observe caregivers significantly more frequently than in the HRS/AHEAD sample. Researchers using HRS/AHEAD data have not modeled duration dependence because of the relatively small number of waves available (for example, Gardner and Gilleskie 2012; Skira 2015).
A. Multiple Caregiver Model
In our Multiple Caregiver Model, the family decides whether to use each potential care arrangement by taking into account characteristics of the elderly individual, characteristics of the care arrangement, and whether the individual relied on that arrangement in the previous period. Excluding the dynamic component, this approach is similar to that of Checkovich and Stern (2002), Brown (2006), and Byrne et al. (2009). In this model, we assume that the family selects each arrangement with a positive latent value without considering interactions across care alternatives.
More technically, we estimate a dynamic multivariate probit model where the baseline latent value of alternative j is given in Equation 1. We assume εnij~iidN(0,1) and define F ω(·) as the joint distribution of ω. Family n uses alternative j to provide care for individual i at time t if and only if y ·ijt > 0; in effect,

Let

where yijt –1 equals one if alternative j was chosen last period, and θ = (β, γ, α, δ, λ, σ η) is the vector of parameters to estimate. Let ait be a dummy variable indicating whether individual i is living at time t.13 Then, the likelihood contribution for an elderly individual i is

It is straightforward to simulate the likelihood contribution for each observation.14 As is true for all the models in the paper, estimating the asymptotic covariance matrix is standard.
B. Initial Conditions Methodology
Initial conditions problems are common to estimation of all dynamic models. In particular, in the other dynamic long-termcare papers, Heitmueller andMichaud (2006) find no significant correlation between errors in the initial and subsequent periods, while Skira (2015) finds important effects associated with initial conditions. In this section,we suggest a new methodology for controlling for initial data year conditions à la Heckman (1981).15 We couch our discussion in terms of the Multiple Caregiver model presented above where decisions are made at time t = Tb
, Tb
+ 1, .., 0, 1, .., Te
, but the same methodology can be used in all three models. We observe
for each observation i where Zit
= (Zi,1,t, Zi,2,t, .., Zi,Jn+4,t). This is an example of the classic initial data year conditions problemin that we must decide how to model the stochastic process for yijt
at time 0.
Imagine that we know or can estimate inverse transition matrices,

and

In some cases, such as age, Xit
j Xit
+1 is degenerate. In others cases such as ADL problems, we can easily estimate px
(Xit
j Xit
+1) with AHEAD/HRS. Alsowe assume that, at Tb
, yijt
= 0, a reasonable assumption in our case since almost all respondents live independently at Tb
. Then, given
, we can easily simulate
(working from t = 0 back to t = Tb
). The simulator may not be continuous, but that does not matter as long as
does not depend on θ.
Given a draw of
, we can now compute

iteratively for t = Tb
, Tb
+1, .., –1, where
is a draw of ui
,
is a draw of vit
, and
is a draw of ηi and ηi = (ηi1, ηi2, .., ηiJn + 4). Note that the
and
draws are used both in the initial period in the data as well as all subsequent periods, thus allowing for the standard initial data year conditions bias described, for example, in Heckman (1981).
Let

Define

and then

for t = Tb
+2, Tb
+3, ..,0.We can add either
to the conditional likelihood function to control for the initial data year conditions. The advantage of this method for this problem is that it involves adding no parameters to the model. This is important here because we do not observe much variation in the first period of data to estimate a set of extra parameters with any precision. The method relies on the existence of a time Tb
in the not-too-distant past where it is reasonable to assume that yijTb
= 0. This methodology has some significant similarities to Ham and Lalonde (1996), though, in their work, there is not the same natural starting point assumption.
C. Estimates of Transition Matrices
Using the proposed initial data year conditions methodology requires estimating the inverse transition matrices defined in Equation 3. Table 4 includes a list of all of the inverse transition models estimated.16 For each model, we include as regressors a constant, dummies for female, black, and Hispanic, age 80, and (age 80)2 and simulate data backwards from the age of the respondent in the initial wave back to age Tb = 60.
Probit estimates for inverse transition into marriage are reported in Table 5. For example, the estimate associated with female in the first panel (-1.456) says that, holding constant other exogenous variables, women are approximately 1.456ϕ(1.229) = 0.273 less likely than are men to have a spouse at t, conditional on not being in the sample at t + 1.17 In effect, women who die between t and t + 1 are less likely to have had a spouse at t than men who die between t and t + 1. The finding that women are less likely than men to be married at the end of life is consistent with differences in life expectancy by gender and age differences between husbands and wives.
Summary of Inverse Transition Probability Estimates
Based on the probit estimates in the first panel of Table 5, Figure 1 shows how inverse transition probabilities for marriage at t conditional on not being in the sample at t + 1 vary with demographic characteristics. In general, women have significantly lower inverse transition rates than men, and blacks and Hispanics have lower inverse transition rates. Age effects increase in magnitude (absolute value) for those with low inverse transition rates because of the nonlinearity of the probit structure. While this particular example is interesting in its own right, it is not relevant for controlling for the initial data year conditions problem because someone who is not in the sample in the initial period (and possibly there the period before) is not included in the data.
Consider the results in the second panel of Table 5 for the probability of being married at t conditional on being in the sample but not married at t + 1; such results are relevant to controlling for initial data year conditions. Note that the estimate of the effect of female is negative (-0.426), implying that women are approximately 0.426ϕ(-1.191) = 0.084 less likely to have a spouse at t conditional on not having one at t + 1 than are men. In effect, it is more likely that an unmarried man lost his wife within the last period than that an unmarried woman lost her husband.18 At first glance, this finding may seem counterintuitive in light of men’s higher death rates. To enhance intuition, consider the following implication of this finding: conditional on being unmarried at t + 1, women are more likely than men to have been unmarried at time t. This finding is consistent with gender differences in life expectancy and age differences betweenmen and women; in effect, among widows and widowers, on average women lost their spouses longer ago.
Probit Estimates for Parent Marital Status
A summary of the significant estimates for the other inverse transitions is reported in Table 4.19 For example, as shown in Table 4, conditional on not being in the sample at time t + 1, black elderly individuals are less likely than white elders to be married at time t, controlling for other exogenous variables. Conditional on being unmarried at time t + 1, black and Hispanic elders are less likely than their white counterparts to be married at time t. Also, not surprisingly, conditional on being unmarried at time t + 1, having a spouse at time t depends negatively on age.
Conditional on the number of ADL problems experienced by the elderly individual at time t + 1, the estimated number of ADL problems at time t is higher for women than for men and for blacks and Hispanics than for whites. Also, as expected, the estimated number ofADLproblems at time t depends positively on age, conditional on the number of ADL problems at time t + 1. Similarly, conditional on the number of IADL problems experienced at time t + 1, the estimated number of IADL problems at time t is higher for women than for men and for blacks than whites. The estimated number of IADL problems at time t also depends positively on age, conditional on the number of IADL problems at time t + 1.
Estimated Probability for Parent Married Conditional on Not in Origin
The spouse’s age, years of education, and activity limitations at time t depend on the respondent’s demographic characteristics, conditional on the spouse’s absence from the sample at time t + 1. For example, conditional on the spouse’s absence from the sample at time t + 1, on average, women have older spouses than do men at time t. The spouse’s activity limitations at time t also depend on demographic characteristics, conditional on the number of activity limitations at time t + 1. For example, conditional on the number of ADL problems experienced by the spouse at time t + 1, husbands (women’s spouses) experience fewer ADL problems than do wives.
Finally, several characteristics of the elderly individual’s children at time t depend on the elderly individual’s demographic characteristics, conditional on the presence of a child at time t + 1, the child’s employment status at time t + 1, or the child’s marital status at time t + 1. For example, conditional on the lack of a child at time t + 1, the probability of a child at time t depends negatively on the parent’s age. The probability that a child worked at time t depends negatively on the parent’s age, regardless of whether the child works at time t + 1. Conditional on working at time t + 1, the probability that the child worked at time t is lower in black and Hispanic families than in white families.
In the Heckman (1981) approach to initial conditions, one adds a large number of extra parameters that allow the likelihood contribution of the initial data year condition to be essentially unrelated to the likelihood contributions of subsequent periods except for potential correlation of errors. In other words, the joint density of the initial data period and subsequent periods can be decomposed into (a) the density of subsequent periods conditional on the initial period multiplied by (b) the density of the initial period. Given all of the extra parameters used to parameterize (b), the parameters associated with (a) are identified essentially by the joint density of subsequent periods conditional on the initial period. In our methodology, the restriction imposed on the initial data year condition is that the same parameters that affect behavior in subsequent periods must explain behavior in the initial period as well, though in a different way because transitions between time periods Tb and 0 are not observed in the data. Thus, the structural parameters are identified by the product of (a) and (b). The fact that the estimates with and without the initial data year conditions correction are closely tied suggests that our specification of the process to reach the initial data year condition is modeled in a reasonable way.
D. Multiple Caregiver Results
Table 6 presents the multivariate probit results. Several demographic characteristics significantly influence the value of each potential care arrangement.20 Controlling for marital status, age, activity limitations, educational attainment, and several characteristics of the spouse, families value each mode of care statistically significantly more highly for men than for women. Although inconsistent with some of the findings in the literature (for example, McGarry 1998; Pezzin and Schone 1999b; Checkovich and Stern 2002), the implication that families value informal care more highly for elderly men than for elderly women is consistent with the implications of the game-theoretic analysis in Byrne et al. (2009); specifically, the findings presented in Byrne et al. (2009) suggest that care provided to mothers is less effective (albeit also less burdensome) than care provided to fathers.
Multiple Caregiver—Multivariate Probit Estimates
Activity limitations and age significantly influence the value of care arrangements. The value of each mode of care depends positively and, with one exception, statistically significantly on the number of ADL and IADL problems experienced by an elderly individual. Controlling for activity limitations and the age of the spouse, as the individual ages, spousal care becomes less valuable, while the other modes of care become more valuable.
Consistent with the literature (for example, Stern 1995; Hoerger, Picone, and Sloan 1996; Rainer and Siedler 2009), our results imply that spouses are an important source of care for one another. At first glance, the sign and the statistical significance of the relationships between marital status and institutional care and between marital status and care provided by an adult child suggests that families value these care arrangements significantly more highly for unmarried than for married elders.21 However, some spousal characteristics mitigate the direct effect of marital status. In fact, for most combinations of spousal characteristics within the range of our sample, families value institutional care more highly for married than for unmarried individuals. An exception concerns individuals whose spouses are relatively young (under about 70 years), healthy (no activity limitations), and highly educated (college degree). Whether families value care provided by an adult child more or less highly for married individuals than for their otherwise identical unmarried counterparts depends on the characteristics of the spouse. For example, unless the spouse is very old (about 88 years or older), the estimates suggest that families value care provided by a child less highly for a married individual whose college-educated spouse is healthy than for an unmarried but otherwise identical individual. In the case of elderly individuals whose spouses are about 71 years or older, less healthy (one ADL and one IADL problem) and less educated (no high school degree). However, the estimates suggest that families value care provided by an adult child more highly than if the individual were unmarried but otherwise identical. For all combinations of spousal characteristics in our sample, families value formal home healthcare more highly for married than for unmarried individuals.
Our results also shed light on the role of adult children’s characteristics in families’ long-term care arrangements for elderly individuals. Consistent with the literature (for example, Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger 1997; Wolf, Freedman, and Soldo 1997; Checkovich and Stern 2002; Engers and Stern 2002), child gender is associated with informal care provision—at least among white families.22 Our results suggest that white families value daughters more than sons as caregivers, after controlling for other demographic characteristics. Children who live near but not with their elderly parents are valued more highly as caregivers than are those living more than 10 miles away.23
Several market conditions and public policies in the elderly individual’s state of residence also significantly influence care arrangements. After controlling for activity limitations and other relevant factors, the attractiveness of formal home healthcare depends negatively on the average wages of home healthcare providers and positively on the generosity of a state’s income limits facing couples (but not single individuals) for Medicaid coverage of formal care. Institutional care is a more attractive option in states with greater nursing home staff hours per nursing home resident.
Although our models explicitly control for health limitations that relate to ADLs and IADLs, the person–time–choice factor loadings (λj) may capture the role of temporary health conditions unrelated to ADL or IADL limitations, while the person–choice factor loadings (δj) may capture the role of chronic health conditions unrelated to ADL or IADL limitations. Estimates of the person–time–choice factor loadings indicate that unobservable person–time-specific heterogeneity influences the value of each nonspousal care arrangement. Thus, the results suggest that temporary health conditions unrelated to activity limitations may influence the relative attractiveness of each nonspousal mode of care and hence may induce changes in care arrangements over time. Meanwhile estimates of the person–choice factor loadings indicate that more permanent sources of unobserved heterogeneity, such as chronic health conditions, also influence the value of each care alternative. In addition to chronic health conditions, the person– choice factor loadings may capture the effect of income and wealth. Collectively these results highlight the importance of controlling for unobserved heterogeneity in modeling families’ care arrangements over time.
Moreover, the results provide evidence of true positive state dependence or inertia across all modes of care. This finding probably reflects the substantial economic and psychological costs associated with transitions into and out of care arrangements. To the extent that caregiver burnout contributes to negative true state dependence, its effect is dominated by inertia. While it would be very useful to estimate the two effects separately, there is no information in the transition data that would allow for separate identification. 24However, there are other sources of data with direct measures of burnout that might allowfor a decomposition of the total effect into its two components (for example, Pezzin, Kemper, and Reschovsky 1996; Coe and Van Houtven 2009). The psychology literature contains much work on direct measurement of burnout (for example, Lawton et al. 1991; McFall and Miller 1992; Goode et al. 1998; Li, Seltzer, and Greenberg 1999; Seltzer and Li 2000; Roth et al. 2001; Gaugler et al. 2005a, 2005b; Hirst 2005; Perren, Schmid, and Wettstein 2006). The problem with applying this literature or the data behind the literature is that the investigated burnout is over much shorter periods of time than that used in this paper.
We also estimated a static multivariate probit model where care arrangements in the previous period do not influence current care arrangements (in effect, we restrict αj = 0). Most of the parameter estimates associated with the static model are consistent in sign with those of the dynamic model, but, not surprisingly, their magnitudes tend to be larger and more statistically significant. For example, the relationship between the generosity of a state’s Medicaid policy and the value of formal home healthcare is larger and more statistically significant in the static model. Perhaps some characteristics matter more in the initial choice of the care arrangement than in the current decision conditional on past decisions. Also, in the model with dynamics, the measured effects are associated with flows, while, in the static model, the measured effects are associated with a stock of present and future flows (for example, Berkovec and Stern 1991).
To illustrate more formally how the effects may be associated with flows consider a simple dynamic programming problem with choices each period
and utility flow u(dt
, Xdt
α) + εt(dt
), where Xdt
is a vector of exogenous state variables25 and26

Then the value of choosing dt is

and, given the error distribution assumption,

Identification of α relies on covariation of Xj with frequency of choice j being chosen (for all j), and27


Almost always,
has the same sign as
because V(dt
+1) is just a weighted sum of future utility flows, many of which will have dτ = j for τ > t. In other words, if Xj
α increases u( j, Xj
α) at time t, then it will do so also at future times when choice j is chosen. Let
be the sample analog of
. The estimation procedure is going to match
, with the value of ∂Pr[dt
= j]/∂SXj
implied by the model and parameters. In a dynamic model, where 0 < β < 1, some of the theoretical derivative can be captured in
, while, in a static model, where β = 0, all of the theoretical value has to be explained by ∂u( j, Xj
α)/∂Xj
. In general, if

with multiplication factor m > 0,28 then the estimate of α in the static model and the estimate in the dynamic model must satisfy

which implies

Evidence of inertia in care arrangements and the sensitivity of parameter estimates across our static and dynamic models underscore the importance of developing models that capture intertemporal patterns of care. As discussed earlier, most of the models in this literature are static (for example, Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger 1997; Pezzin and Schone 1999a; Engers and Stern 2002; Pezzin, Pollak, and Schone 2007; Byrne et al. 2009). While a few studies present dynamic models (Garber and MaCurdy 1990; Börsch-Supan, Kotlikoff, and Morris 1991; Dostie and Léger 2005; Heitmueller and Michaud 2006; Gardner and Gilleskie 2012), our models encompass a broader range of care arrangements.
E. Primary Caregiver Model
Much of the long-term care literature focuses on the selection of the primary care arrangement for an elderly individual (for example, Hiedemann and Stern 1999; Engers and Stern 2002), but all of the existing models of the primary care arrangement are static in nature. In our Primary Caregiver Model, the family selects the primary care arrangement for an elderly individual in a particular time period taking into account the characteristics of the potential care recipient, the characteristics of the potential care arrangements, and the primary care arrangement selected the previous period. The primary care arrangement is the arrangement with the highest latent value. If the value of each potential care arrangement is less than the value of remaining independent, the individual receives no care.29
More technically, we estimate a multinomial mixed logit model (McFadden and Train 2000) where the baseline latent value to alternative j is given in Equation 1 and εijt~ iidEV. Assume the family chooses the alternative that provides the highest latent value; in effect,

where the set of care alternatives at time t is denoted Sit . Let

with parameters given by θ. The lagged care decision, yijt –1 is a dummy variable equal to one if care arrangement j was the primary arrangement in the previous period. Then the likelihood contribution for family n is

where F ω(·) is the joint distribution of the unobservables. There is no closed-form solution to Equation 6, so we estimate the model using maximum simulated likelihood estimation. The simulated likelihood contribution is

where
are errors simulated from their respective densities (Börsch-Supan, Kotlikoff, and Morris 1991; Hajivassiliou, McFadden, and Ruud 1996). As discussed earlier, we control for initial data year conditions as described in Section IV.B.
F. Primary Caregiver Results
Table 7 presents multinomial mixed logit parameter estimates for the choice of the primary care arrangement. The roles of demographic characteristics and activity limitations in the decision to use a particular mode of care are often similar to their roles in the selection of the primary care arrangement. For example, as in the Multiple Caregiver Model, controlling for marital status, age, activity limitations, educational attainment, and several characteristics of the spouse, families value each mode of care more highly for men than for women. Also, as an elderly individual develops more activity limitations, the value of each mode of care tends to increase as an arrangement (in Table 6) and as the primary care arrangement (in Table 7).
As in the Multiple Caregiver Model, our results imply that marital status and spousal characteristics influence families’ eldercare arrangements. Marital status per se is significantly associated with the value of informal care provided by an adult child and formal home healthcare but not with institutional care. However, the spouse’s age and activity limitations (as measured by the number of ADL problems and/or the number of IADL problems) influence the value of each mode of care, while the spouse’s educational attainment influences the value of care provided by an adult child. Consistent with the implications of our Multiple Caregiver Model, our estimates suggest that families tend to place more value on both modes of formal care as the primary arrangement for married than for unmarried elderly individuals. An exception concerns individuals whose spouses who are relatively young and healthy; for example, all else equal, the estimates suggest that a family would value formal home healthcare more highly for an unmarried individual than for a married individual whose 60-year-old, college-educated spouse has no activity limitations. Again, whether families value care provided by an adult child more or less highly for married individuals than for their otherwise identical unmarried counterparts depends on the characteristics of the spouse.
Primary Caregiver—Multinomial Mixed Logit Estimates
As in the Multiple Caregiver Model, characteristics of the younger generation influence families’ care arrangements. Again, white families value daughters statistically significantly more than sons as caregivers. Proximity to or coresidence with elderly parents positively influences an adult child’s value as primary caregiver. Although marriage significantly enhances an adult child’s value as a caregiver, marriage significantly reduces her value as the primary caregiver.
Market conditions and public policies significantly influence the value of formal care arrangements in both discrete-choice models. For example, the value of formal home healthcare as an arrangement or as the primary arrangement depends negatively on the cost of home health aide workers, and the value of institutional care depends positively on the nursing home staff hours per resident in the individual’s state of residence.
As discussed earlier, the person–time–choice factor loadings (λj) may capture the role of temporary health conditions unrelated toADLor IADL limitations, while the person– choice factor loading (δj) may capture the role of chronic health conditions unrelated to activity limitations. As in the Multiple Caregiver Model, estimates for the person–time– choice factor loadings indicate that person–time-specific heterogeneity significantly influences the values of nonspousal care arrangements. Thus, the results of this model suggest that temporary health conditions unrelated to ADL and IADL limitations may change the relative attractiveness of each nonspousal mode of care and hence may induce a change in the individual’s primary care arrangement. Estimates for the person– choice factor loadings indicate that unobservable person-specific characteristics significantly influence the value of care provided by an adult child. This finding may reflect variation in caregiver burden depending on the presence or severity of chronic health conditions.
As in the Multiple Caregiver Model, the results of the Primary Caregiver Model provide evidence of true state dependence in eldercare arrangements. The signs of the relevant parameter estimates suggest that inertia contributes to care arrangements in the case of informal care provided by a spouse or an adult child and in the case of institutional care. Intuitively, the high costs of transitioning from one care arrangement to another or the accumulation of human capital specific to caregiving may lead families to maintain their primary care arrangement for an elderly relative. While three of the four modes of care display positive state dependence, formal home healthcare displays negative state dependence.30 However, since a family could replace a burned-out home health aide, negative state dependence probably cannot be attributed to caregiver burnout in the case of formal home healthcare. Instead, negative state dependence may reflect a tendency to rely on formal home healthcare (i) for acute rather than chronic health conditions, (ii) as a temporary measure until an informal caregiver becomes available, or (iii) until the parent needs institutional care. Thus, while both discrete-choice models provide evidence of inertia in informal modes of care and institutional care, the models differ with regard to their implications concerning the use of formal home healthcare over time. Collectively the two sets of results suggest that inertia dominates caregiver burden in families’ decisions to rely on a formal home health aide in conjunction with other modes of care but that the reliance on a formal home health aide as the primary caregiver tends to be temporary.
G. Hours of Care Model
An important dimension of caregiving decisions concerns how much care each caregiver provides. Following Sloan, Picone, and Hoerger (1997), Wolf, Freedman, and Soldo (1997), Pezzin and Schone (1999b), Checkovich and Stern (2002), and Byrne et al. (2009), we next consider the continuous choice associated with care arrangements. As discussed earlier, families may rely on more than one mode of care. For example, an elderly individual may receive informal care provided by a child together with formal care provided by a home health aide (Bolin et al. 2008). As this example suggests, various caregiving alternatives—and the amount provided—may be substitutable to some extent. Moreover, the quantity of care received in the past could influence the value associated with the quantity of that care alternative provided today (U.S. Department of Health and Human Services 1999). Accordingly, our Hours of Care Model allows for the possibility of multiple care arrangements, while linking arrangements over time.
We estimate a dynamic multivariate tobit model, where we augment the baseline latent value of care in Equation 1 to allowfor substitution across modes of care as well as different effects of true state dependence. We treat nursing home care differently than other care arrangements as we do not observe hours of care when a parent is in a nursing home. Let j = –2 for nursing home, j = –1 for formal care, j = 0 for care by spouse, and j > 0 for care by the jth child. Specifically, the latent value associated with the amount of time spent using the jth care arrangement is

In terms of its substitution effect, we distinguish between nursing homes and other alternatives. For alternatives other than nursing home care, j>-2, the observed continuous value of caregiving is given by
and
. For nursing home care, j = –2, the observed binary measure of caregiving is given by
because we do not observe a continuous measure of nursing home care hours. Similar to Checkovich and Stern (2002), substitution in total care provided across alternatives is captured by
and
.31 The αj terms capture true state dependence in caregiving where the hours in mode j depends both on whether j was chosen in the previous period (captured by the threshold value of true state dependence, αthresh) and on the quantity of alternative j provided in the previous period (captured by the marginal value of true state dependence, αmarg). The parameters to estimate are σe, and
.
Let

The likelihood contribution for an individual i is

where Fω(·) denotes the joint distribution of the unobservables,



Note that, for j > -2, the likelihood contribution is a conditional tobit term, and, for j = –2, it is a conditional probit term. We simulate Equation 8 by drawing values of ω from its distribution (with antithetic acceleration). Again, we control for initial model year conditions by constructing
from Equation 4 in the appropriate fashion and adding it to the conditional likelihood function.
H. Hours of Care Results
Table 8 presents the results of our dynamic multivariate tobit model. The results of this model reinforce the importance of controlling for unobserved heterogeneity.Estimates for the person–time–choice factor loadings indicate that person–time-specific heterogeneity significantly influences the values of bothmodes of informal care, as well as institutional care. Thus, these results suggest that temporary health conditions unrelated to ADL and IADL limitationsmay change the relative attractiveness of these modes of care and hence may induce changes in the amount of informal care or the use of institutional care over time. Estimates for the person–choice factor loadings are not statistically significant.
All modes of care exhibit statistically significant true state dependence. The quantity of each mode of noninstitutional care in the current period depends positively on whether that mode was used in the previous period—a threshold inertia effect, while the quantity of eachmode of informal care depends positively on the quantity used in the previous period—a marginal inertia effect. Thus, the results again indicate that, to the extent that caregiver burden influences long-term care arrangements, its impact tends to be dominated by inertia. Not surprisingly, the reliance on institutional care depends positively on whether the individual was institutionalized in the previous period.
Hours of Caregiving—Multivariate Tobit Estimates
Contrary to our expectations and to the literature (for example, Checkovich and Stern 2002; Van Houtven and Norton 2004), the estimated substitution effects indicate that the quantity of each mode of noninstitutional care and the use of institutional care depend positively on the total amount of care currently received from other sources. The positive effects associated with informal care provided by a child may reflect competition among children for a bequest (Bernheim, Shleifer, and Summers 1985). However, a bequest motive of this sort would not explain the positive substitution effects associated with the other modes of care. Instead, the number of ADL and IADL problems may not adequately capture long-term care needs, in which case our estimated substitution effects may be biased. More generally, the positive substitution effects may reflect parent-specific unobserved heterogeneity not captured by our model specification. Characteristics that significantly increase (decrease) the latent value of using a particular mode of care often significantly increase (decrease) hours spent in that mode of care. For example, activity limitations tend to increase the attractiveness of formal as well as informal care arrangements. Likewise, hours in each arrangement depend positively on the number of activity limitations. Consistent with expectations and mostly consistent with the implications of the discrete-choice models, adult children who live with or near their elderly parents provide more assistance than do their geographically distant counterparts.
A few market conditions and public policies significantly influence the quantity of formal care received by the elderly individual. Consistent with our other models, the quantity of formal home healthcare depends negatively on the average wages of home healthcare providers. The quantity of formal home healthcare depends positively on the generosity of a state’s Medicaid income limits facing individuals. As expected, the likelihood of selecting institutional care depends positively on daily nursing home staff hours per resident.
V. Policy Implications
For each of our dynamic models, we present the marginal effects associated with the characteristics that have the most relevance from a public policy perspective. In particular, Table 9 displays the marginal effects associated with the market conditions and public policies in the elderly individual’s state of residence.
The statistical significance of the estimated marginal effects suggests that the cost of formal home healthcare influences all three dimensions of families’ long-term care decisions. However, while the magnitude of the effect on hours is economically significant among families relying on formal home healthcare, the magnitudes of the other marginal effects suggest that changes in the cost of formal home healthcare would need to be relatively large in order to induce practically significant changes in the discrete dimensions of care. As indicated in the top panel of Table 9, as the weekly cost of fulltime formal home healthcare increases by $100, the predicted probability that the elderly individual receives this mode of care falls by 0.41 percentage points. As shown in the middle panel, the cost of formal home healthcare also influences the selection of the primary care arrangement. In response to a $100 increase in the weekly cost of full-time care, the predicted probability of relying on formal home healthcare as the primary arrangement falls by 0.19 percentage points, while the predicted probability of living independently increases by 0.14 percentage points.32 Finally, as shown in the bottom panel, conditional on receiving formal home healthcare, an increase of $100 in its weekly cost is associated with a 15 percentage point reduction (about 16.8 hours) in the predicted quantity of formal home healthcare.
Marginal Effects for Market Conditions and Public Policies on Probabilities
The existing literature provides mixed evidence concerning the effects of state-level Medicaid policy on nursing home utilization. Cutler and Sheiner (1994) report a positive and statistically significant relationship between the presence of a medically needy program and the probability of nursing home use. Similarly, Engers and Stern (2002) suggest that the presence of a medically needy program enhances the value of nursing home care. In contrast,Aykan (2002) does not find a statistically significant relationship between the presence of a medically needy program and the likelihood of institutional care. Likewise, Grabowski and Gruber (2007) report that the availability of a medically needy program is not statistically significantly associated with nursing home use. Consistent with Cutler and Sheiner and Engers and Stern (2002), the presence of a medically needy program has a very small but positively and statistically significant effect on the use of institutional care in our discrete-choice models. Our results indicate that the presence of a medically needy program is associated with statistically significant increases in predicted hours of formal home healthcare.
Care arrangements depend on the generosity of the state’s income limits for Medicaid eligibility. In response to a $1,000 increase in the monthly income limit facing unmarried individuals, the predicted probabilities that a lone elder relies on formal home healthcare or institutional care increase by 13.4 and 22.6 percentage points, respectively, while the predicted probabilities that she relies on these arrangements as the primary arrangement increase by 6.5 and 3.3 percentage points.33 The positive and statistically significant relationship between income limits and nursing home use is consistent with economic theory and Gardner and Gilleskie (2012) but inconsistent with Grabowski and Gruber (2007). It is worth noting that Grabowski and Gruber (2007) set income limits to zero in states with spend-down provisions, while we use the actual income limits for all states. Among lone elders who receive formal home healthcare, predicted hours increase by 45.4 ( = 0.27*168) hours per week as the income limit increases by $1,000. The effects of income limits are smaller but are sometimes negative for married individuals.
The use of institutional care depends on the quality and availability of care in the elderly individual’s state of residence. For example, the predicted probability of relying on institutional care depends positively on the availability of nursing home beds. Surprisingly, however, the predicted probabilities of relying on institutional care as an arrangement or as the primary arrangement depend negatively on nursing home staff hours per resident.
VI. Specification and Robustness Checks
In this section, we address several limitations of our data and models. First, we explore whether including income and wealth (even though the data are of poor quality) would improve the fit of our models. Second, we test whether state/mode- specific effects and other state-specific effects not included in our models influence care arrangements. Third, we examine whether the distance between an elderly parent and an adult child is endogenous. Finally, we present specification checks by allowing for a richer covariance structure.
A. Income and Wealth Data
As we discussed in Section III, the measures of income and assets/wealth in the AHEAD/HRS may not be reliable. Therefore, we chose not to let our models include income or wealth effects. Here, we present several alternative specifications to test whether adding income or wealth would significantly improve the fit of our models. In light of the findings in Gardner and Gilleskie (2012) that an important effect of wealth operates through its interactions with state Medicaid rules, we also examine interactions of income and wealth with policy characteristics. To facilitate comparison with Gardner and Gilleskie (2012) and Byrne et al. (2009), we use 1998 and 1993 Medicaid income and asset limits as well as dummy variables indicating the presence of a medically needy program. For each model, we estimate several additional specifications. In addition to income or wealth, these specifications include income or wealth interacted with Medicaid income or asset limits, as well as the presence of a medically needy program. One of the wealth specifications excludes observations with missing information on wealth. Since the lack of information concerning wealth may not be random, the remaining wealth specifications include a dummy variable formissing wealth data.34WhileGardner and Gilleskie (2012) treat the Medicaid asset limit as a discrete cutoff, our approach accommodates the possibility that individuals just above the limit may spend down and thus behave similarly to those who are just below the limit.35 In particular, we include “smoothed” assets in our third wealth specification.36 To reduce the influence of large fluctuations in reported wealth, the final specification replaces the individual’s current wealth with her average wealth over the observed time frame.
Table 10 presents the results of Lagrange Multiplier tests for each model specification. 37 The top panel displays the results concerning income and its interactions, while the bottom panel displays the results concerning wealth and its interactions. For each specification, we conduct a joint chi-square test, as well as separate chi-square tests for each restriction. Consistent with Gardner and Gilleskie (2012), the results indicate that the fit of the Multiple Caregiver Model would be improved by including income and its interactions with the 1998 Medicaid policy characteristics: the score statistics associated with income interacted with the presence of a medically needy program and income interacted with Medicaid income limits are individually and jointly statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance. However, the corresponding score statistics associated with 1993 Medicaid policy characteristics are neither individually nor jointly significant. Moreover, the score statistics associated with income itself are not statistically significant. For the Primary Caregiver Model, the score statistics associated with income and its interactions with 1998 Medicaid policy characteristics are jointly statistically significant. While the score statistic associated with income and its interaction with the Medicaid income limit is individually statistically significant, the score statistics associated with income itself and with income and its interaction with the presence of a medically needy program are not. In the Hours of Care Model, income and its interactions with Medicaid policy are jointly significant for both Medicaid limit years. However, only the interactions between income and the presence of a medically needy program and income and Medicaid income limits in 1993 have a statistically significant score statistic. For all three models, the score statistics associated with wealth and its interactions are jointly statistically significant, but most of the individual score statistics associated with wealth or its interactions are not statistically significant.
Income and Assets Lagrange Multiplier Tests
The mixed evidence concerning the interactions between income and the presence of a medically needy program or between income and Medicaid income limits may be attributable to the poor quality of the income data and the nonlinearity of the interactions between income and policy characteristics. For example, we would expect minimal effects of a medically needy program on vPr[NHcare]/vIncome except near the relevant income limit. We did not allow for such nonlinearity, nor did Gardner and Gilleskie (2012). Furthermore, if there are higher nonresponse rates for income associated with higher incomes near the relevant limit, our test statistics may be biased towards zero. Similarly, the mixed evidence concerning the interaction between wealth and policy characteristics may partially reflect the poor quality of the wealth data. Collectively, the results provide mixed evidence in favor of including measures of income and wealth even when interacted with Medicaid policy characteristics.
B. State-Specific Effects
Although our models include several market conditions and public policies in the elderly individual’s or couple’s state of residence, the models may not capture all statespecific/ mode-specific or other state-specific effects. For example, other nursing home regulations, the supply of home health aides, or state-specific variation in cultural attitudes may influence families’ care decisions. Accordingly, our next set of specification tests concerns the possibility of state-specific/mode-specific fixed effects. Using observations from states where there is more than one elderly household in our sample, we perform Lagrange Multiplier tests to test the null hypothesis of no state-specific/modespecific fixed effects. In particular, we amend the baseline model in Equation 1 to

where dnis
is a dummy variable equal to 1 if and only if parent i in family n lives in state s. Under the null hypothesis, τjs = 0 for all choices and all states s.38 The overall
is 1850.7, which is statistically significant. However, the vast majority of the individual score statistics are statistically insignificant, and there is no obvious pattern associated with those that are significant.39
Next, we compare our state-specific/mode-specific score statistics for the two formal modes of care to 1997 utilization rates based on data presented in LeBlanc, Tonner, and Harrington (2000). We translate their data into log(nursing home utilization per 1000 individuals aged 70 or over) and log(number of Medicaid waivers per 1000 individuals aged 70 or over). After excluding states with missing state-specific dummy score statistics and/or utilization rates along with one outlier,40 we use data from the remaining 31 states to compute the correlations between the score statistics and the utilization rates. For the Multiple Caregiver Model, the correlations are roughly 0.38 for nursing home care and 0.09 for formal home healthcare. The correlations are smaller for the other two models. These results imply that observed variation across states in nursing home use is not tied to the state-specific dummies in Equation 9, and we find only weak evidence that state-specific characteristics not included in our models affect nursing home usage.
C. Geographic Distance
Geographic distance between elderly individuals and their adult children may be endogenous. For example, children may move closer to their parents or vice versa as their parents age or develop health problems. For families with at least one child, Table 11 presents the overall location transitions of children relative to parents based on the three possible responses in AHEAD/HRS: coresidence, living within 10 miles, and living more than 10 miles away. For each family size, the probabilities on the diagonals reveal strong persistence in geographic distance. For example, among families where the parent and child are initially more than 10 miles apart, the proportion later coresiding ranges from 0.008 to 0.029, depending on family size; similarly, the proportion later living within 10 miles ranges from 0.005 to 0.011.
Next we examine location transitions in response to increased caregiving needs. Table 12 displays location transitions among families where at least one child initially lives more than 10 miles from her parent(s) and subsequently coresides with her parent(s). For each of these families, we follow all initially distant children who provide no care in the first year until one becomes the primary caregiver (if ever). Column 1 reports the proportion of children who transition to coresidence with the parent among families where the parent experiences an increase in the number of ADL problems. Column 2 indicates the proportion of those children from Column 1 who become the primary caregiver. Columns 3 and 4 indicate the comparable proportions among families where the parent experiences no change in the number of ADL problems. Under the null hypothesis that changes in child location are exogenous, we would expect the proportions in Columns 1 and 2 to be small, those in Columns 1 and 3 to be similar, and those in Columns 2 and 4 to be similar. For families with one or two children, the proportions in the first two columns are statistically significantly larger than those that would be predicted by a model with the transition rates presented in Table 11. Also, for such families, the proportion of children who become the primary caregiver (Column 2) is statistically significantly larger than what would be predicted by a model where location transitions are exogenous.We find similar results corresponding to increases in the number of IADL problems. These results suggest that location transitions may be endogenous. To further examine the nature of the endogeneity, without the need to reestimate all the alternative specifications, we construct a likelihood-ratio test to decompose the effect of location into initial (exogenous) location and contemporaneous (possibly endogenous) location.
Location Transitions
Recall that our original model captures the effect of location on care provision as

where zikt 6 is a dummy variable that equals one if child k lives within 10 miles of the parent i in year t and zikt 7 is a dummy variable that equals one if child k lives with the parent i in year t. To further explore the possible endogeneity of location, we construct a likelihood ratio test to decompose the effect of location into two components: an initial, presumably exogenous location and a current, possibly endogenous component. Here we estimate a version of the Multiple Caregiver Model that specifies the effect of location on care provision as

Under the null hypothesis that the model is correctly specified, γ6 = γ6a, and γ7 = γ7a. Alternatively, if location transitions have a different effect on care than does initial location, then γ6sγ6a, and γ7sγ7a. As shown in Table 13, the likelihood-ratio test suggests that we should reject the null hypothesis that the model is correctly specified, but the Wald tests suggest we should not reject the null. However, the similarity of the initial and transition parameters suggests that any endogeneity in location transitions would cause small bias (conditional on the exogeneity of initial location). Thus, as long as initial location is exogenous, we do not find strong evidence that an estimate associated with current location is affected by potential endogeneity issues.41 To summarize, (i) there is some evidence of endogeneity of geographic location, (ii) location transitions occur infrequently enough to make it impossible to correct for bias associated caused by endogeneity, and (iii) there is also evidence that any such bias is very small in magnitude.42
ADL Test Results for Primary Caregiver Model
VII. Conclusions
We contribute to the long-term care literature by developing and estimating three dynamic models of families’ care arrangements for the elderly. Our dynamic framework links care arrangements over time by allowing for true and spurious state dependence. Controlling for observable characteristics of the potential care recipients and the potential care providers and allowing for several types of unobserved heterogeneity, we isolate the impact of true state dependence. In theory, state dependence could be positive or negative, depending on the relative importance of caregiver burden and inertia. Our results provide strong evidence of positive state dependence in care arrangements. Thus, to the extent that caregiver burnout contributes to long-term care arrangements, its effects are generally dominated by inertia.
Likelihood-Ratio and Wald Tests for Location Endogeneity
In addition, our results provide important policy implications. The effects of market conditions and public policies on the use of formal home healthcare and institutional care are smaller and less statistically significant in our dynamic model than in an otherwise identical static model. This pattern suggests that the measured effects in the dynamic model reflect flows while those in the static model reflect a stock of present and future flows. Nevertheless, even after allowing for state dependence, families’ care decisions depend on the cost, quality, and availability of formal modes of care.
As an early step towards understanding the dynamics of families’ long-term care arrangements, this work abstracts from the possibility that family members have different preferences. In future work, we plan to examine the strategic aspects of long-term care decisions in a dynamic setting by developing and estimating dynamic gametheoretic models. The appropriate game-theoretic model depends on the dimension of care examined. For example, in the interest of parsimony, a model of families’ selection of the primary care arrangement may abstract from the possibility of other caregivers. On the other hand, a model that allows for multiple caregivers might focus on each family member’s decision whether to provide care. A model of the continuous dimension of care arrangements might focus on hours within each arrangement while explaining the pattern of a primary caregiver. The models presented here provide useful insights concerning the development of appropriate structural dynamic models.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank Jan Boone, Liliana Pezzin, and participants at the 2010 International Conference on Evidence-Based Policy in Long-Term Care, the 2011 Annual Meetings of the Population Association of America, the University of Leuven Public Economics Workshop, the University of Pennsylvania Structural Workshop in Honor of Ken Wolpin, the 2013 Annual Southern Economic Association meetings, the 2013 Annual Econometric Society meetings, and seminars at Boston College, IRDES (Paris 2011), the University of Michigan, Peking University, and Tsinghua University for helpful comments. All remaining errors are ours. Most of the data used in this article are public, and some are restricted. The public part can be obtained beginning January 2019 through January 2022 from Steven Stern, Stony Brook University (steven.stern{at}stonybrook.edu). One can apply for the restricted part with the owners of the HRS/AHEAD data, and the authors are willing to assist.
Appendix 1 Endogenous Location
To get a sense of the magnitude of bias, even if the first location is endogenous, consider a simple linear model,

where zi 1 is analogous to initial location, and zit is location in each period t = 1, 2 ..,T. Assume that

and

We allow for serial correlation in both uit and zit because they are prevalent in the data and might affect the bias. On the other hand, we ignore the fact that there are other explanatory variables in the model and that yit is really a nonlinear function of explanatory variables and errors. Then, the OLS estimate of (γ,α) has





In our data, T = 5 and ρz is very large (see Table 11), which implies that
is very small. Thus


If ρez ≈ 0 and/or σe/σu is small, then

which implies that the bias for α should be twice as large as that for γ. Since the difference between them in Table 13 is small, under H 0 = α = γ, the bias for both must be small, both in an absolute sense and relative to the estimate in Table 13. Alternatively, if ρez(σe/σu) has the same sign as ρuz and is not that small, then the bias for γ becomes even smaller relative to that for ^a, and the same analysis holds.
To approximate the potential bias due to endogenous location, consider a simpler model,

where Zi is a vector of exogenous explanatory variables and

with

One should think of xi as a dummy equal to 1 if i lives near the parent, qi as the probability that i lives near the parent at an early age, and pi as the probability that the child moves closer to the parent. We allow pi to depend upon the error in Equation 10 causing both pi and xi to be endogenous.43 The μ parameter should be set so that pi matches transition probabilities from far to near seen in the data. Since these transition probabilities are very small, μ must be a large, negative number. If we ignore the endogeneity of xi and use OLS to estimate (γ,β), then



and the asymptotic bias is proportional to


We can use a first-order Taylor series approximation,

and then plug it into the formula for Exi ,

and, for Equation 13,

Since μ is a large negative number,44ϕ(μ) –Φ(μ) is also very small. At the values of Φ (μ) consistent with the data (≈0.02), ϕ(μ) – Φ(μ)≈0.03. Thus,

which is very small. If
is small, then the bias term for β is
where the denominator is

Plugging in our estimate of Φ(μ), the bias is

which should be small relative to α.
Footnotes
1. See Sovinsky and Stern (2016) for an overview and Mazzocco (2007) for some recent work.
2. We define positive state dependence as a situation where the probability of staying increases with duration (in effect, inertia). Note that our definition is in contrast to the survival analysis literature, which defines state dependence as the probability of leaving (Lancaster 1990).
3. Hill (2006) performs an experiment with later waves of HRS where respondents are told how they answered the asset questions in the last wave; this results in a significant reduction in the variance of asset changes.
4. In addition, long-term care insurance (LTCI) may be an important determinant of care arrangement choices. In our sample, only 10 percent of respondents have long-term care insurance, so we did not include LTCI ownership as a characteristic. However, we performed Lagrange Multiplier tests to determine if LTCI ownership has an impact on care choices. The test statistics are not significant in any of the models, indicating that LTCI ownership does not have a significant impact on long-term care choices.
5. For most respondents, the first year of data used in our analysis is 1995; for some, it is later.
6. The AHEAD data project surveys respondents aged 70 or older in the first wave from 1993.
7. Wages for home health aide workers were obtained from PHI (2007). The nursing home data were obtained from Grabowski et al. (2004) and Harrington, Carrillo, and LaCava (2006).
8. We are using these data for all years.
9. It was not possible for us to find state Medicaid eligibility criteria for all state–year combinations in our sample. Our data are available in the Online Appendix at http://jhr.uwpress.org/.
10. We augment the continuous choice model to allow for substitution across types of care.
11. We estimated a number of different specifications in which we experimented with different error structures.
12. See, also, for example, Alessie, Hochguertel, and van Soest (2004) and Aguirregabiria and Mira (2010).
13. We do not distinguish between attrition and death.
14. For all models, we use antithetic acceleration in simulation. Geweke (1988) shows that, for maximum likelihood estimation, for a large class of models, if antithetic acceleration is implemented during simulation, then the loss in precision is of order 1/N (where N is the number of observations), which requires no adjustment to the asymptotic covariance matrix.
15. See also Dostie and Léger (2005) for another application using Heckman (1981) specific to dynamic family caregiving models.
16. We do not estimate parent marriage at t conditional on being married at t + 1 because we do not observe enough remarriages in the data.We also do not estimate child distance at t conditional on child distance at t + 1 because child migration is very rare in the data. See section (5.3) or the “child distance tabs” in the Online Appendix at http://jhr.uwpress.org/ for estimates of child mobility.
17. Let δ be the set of coefficients whose estimates are reported in Table 5. Note that $$$. ϕ(·) is evaluated at 1.229, the mean value of Xδ based on the reported means in Table 1 and the parameter estimates in the first panel of Table 5. For the purposes of this exercise, we treat discrete explanatory variables as if they were continuous.
18. The value -1.191 is the mean of Xδ based on the sample means from Table 1 and the estimates in the second panel of Table 5.
19. See the Online Appendix at http://jhr.uwpress.org/ for point estimates.
20. In this section, our discussion focuses on the relationship between each characteristic and the latent value of using a particular mode of care relative to the outcome where the individual does not use that mode of care. In a separate section, we present and discuss the marginal effects associated with the most policy-relevant variables.
21. One cannot include a variable for marital status in the spousal care value because a spouse can provide care only if she exists; thus the MLE of such a parameter would be infinity.
22. Again, our discussion focuses on the relationship between each characteristic and the latent value of using a particular mode of care relative to the outcome where the individual does not use that mode of care. Later we present and discuss selected marginal effects.
23. Later in the paper, we address the potential endogeneity of geographic distance. In particular, we test whether the role of the child’s initial (exogenous) location relative to the parent differs from the role of the child’s current (potentially endogenous) location relative to the parent.
24. Byrne et al. (2009) use information on the well-being of the parent to separately identify burnout and caregiver quality in a static model.
25. We can generalize to allow for endogenous stochastic state variables and for state variables that are not specific to a choice.
26. The i.i.d. EVassumption is made to simplify analysis. The basic point does not rely on it.
27. Given the iidEV assumption, the proportionality factor is Pr[dt = j](1 – Pr[dt = j]).
28. If, for example, j is an absorbing state, then $$$. If β = 0.95, then m → 20 as T → N, and m ≈ 5.3 at T = 5.
29. In a structural dynamic model, the family would also consider the dynamic effect of choices today on the value of choices in the future.
30. In the raw data, the transition rate out of formal care is 25 percent higher than for any other care alternative.
31. Checkovich and Stern (2002) do not distinguish between the effects of nursing home care and alternatives.
32. The marginal effects associated with the Primary Caregiver Model sum to one. As a result of rounding error the marginal effects associated with independent living may differ from one minus the sum of the marginal effects reported in Table 7.
33. Notice that, to obtain the impact of a simulating a $100 increase in monthly income, one can divide by 10.
34. Wealth includes all assets. We use SSI Medicaid income limits for singles or couples, depending on the individual’s marital status. Although adding dummy variables is a common way to handle missing values, Abbrevaya and Donald (2011) suggest that this approach may not always provide the desired result.
35. Norton (1995) reports evidence that welfare aversion among the elderly actually leads to the opposite pattern as individuals seek to avoid Medicaid eligibility.
36. LetWit be the wealth of family i at time t, and let Ci be the state-specific asset limit. The smoothed asset limit rule we apply is $$$
37. We conduct a variety of Lagrange Multiplier tests to explore alternative ways to include income and wealth. The value of these tests is that they allow us to examine the relative fit of a variety of specifications that include income and wealth without requiring us to reestimate the model for each specification.
38. We include only states where there is more than one observation.
39. The methodology and the results can be found at http://jhr.uwpress.org/.
40. We exclude Oregon because the value of log (utilization of nursing homes per capita 70 years or older) is six standard deviations below the mean, while all other states used are within one standard deviation.
41. We also tested whether location was endogenous in the Primary Caregiver Model. The results are consistent with those presented here.
42. We include more details in Appendix 1.
43. This is equivalent to adding a different error in Equation 11 and allowing it to be correlated with εi. There would be another scaling factor in Equation 11, but we can ignore this without loss of generality.
- Received February 2013.
- Accepted February 2017.